Friday, August 16, 2013

Trade Appendix


Appendix 2A: Trade Balance

Table 1

U.S. Trade in Goods and Services - Balance of Payments (BOP) Basis
Value in millions of dollars: 1960 thru 2010
 
Year
Total
Goods
Services
1960
3,508
4,892
-1,384
1961
4,195
5,571
-1,376
1962
3,370
4,521
-1,151
1963
4,210
5,224
-1,014
1964
6,022
6,801
-779
1965
4,664
4,951
-287
1966
2,939
3,817
-878
1967
2,604
3,800
-1,196
1968
250
635
-385
1969
91
607
-516
1970
2,254
2,603
-349
1971
-1,302
-2,260
958
1972
-5,443
-6,416
973
1973
1,900
911
989
1974
-4,293
-5,505
1,212
1975
12,404
8,903
3,501
1976
-6,082
-9,483
3,401
1977
-27,246
-31,091
3,845
1978
-29,763
-33,927
4,164
1979
-24,565
-27,568
3,003
1980
-19,407
-25,500
6,093
1981
-16,172
-28,023
11,851
1982
-24,156
-36,485
12,329
1983
-57,767
-67,102
9,335
1984
-109,072
-112,492
3,420
1985
-121,880
-122,173
294
1986
-138,538
-145,081
6,543
1987
-151,684
-159,557
7,874
1988
-114,566
-126,959
12,393
1989
-93,141
-117,749
24,607
1990
-80,864
-111,037
30,173
1991
-31,135
-76,937
45,802
1992
-39,212
-96,897
57,685
1993
-70,311
-132,451
62,141
1994
-98,493
-165,831
67,338
1995
-96,384
-174,170
77,786
1996
-104,065
-191,000
86,935
1997
-108,273
-198,428
90,155
1998
-166,140
-248,221
82,081
1999
-263,160
-336,171
73,011
2000
-376,749
-445,787
69,038
2001
-361,771
-421,276
59,505
2002
-417,432
-474,491
57,059
2003
-490,984
-540,409
49,425
2004
-605,357
-663,507
58,150
2005
-708,624
-780,730
72,106
2006
-753,288
-835,689
82,401
2007
-696,728
-818,886
122,158
2008
-698,338
-830,109
131,770
2009
-381,272
-505,910
124,637
2010
-500,027
-645,857
145,830
U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Division.
Data presented on a Balance of Payment (BOP) basis. Information on data sources and methodology are available at www.census.gov/foreign-trade/www/press.html.



Table 2

U.S. Merchandise Trade Balance by Major Trading Partner  

 

 
Merchandise trade balance   
In millions of dollars
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
Total
Canada
China
France
Germany
Italy
Japan
Korea
Mexico
Nether
lands
Taiwan
U.K.
 
2000
-436,104
-51,897
-83,833
-9,439
-29,064
-13,982
-81,555
-12,478
-24,577
12,165
-16,097
-1,775
 
2001
-411,899
-52,844
-83,096
-10,544
-29,081
-13,874
-69,022
-13,001
-30,041
9,969
-15,253
-655
 
2002
-468,263
-48,165
-103,065
-9,224
-35,876
-14,164
-69,979
-12,996
-37,146
8,462
-13,766
-7,540
 
2003
-532,350
-51,671
-124,068
-12,166
-39,281
-14,854
-66,032
-13,157
-40,648
9,742
-14,152
-8,967
 
2004
-654,830
-66,480
-162,254
-10,688
-45,850
-17,413
-76,237
-19,981
-45,170
11,689
-13,038
-10,372
 
2005
-772,373
-78,486
-202,278
-11,583
-50,567
-19,485
-83,323
-16,210
-49,861
11,606
-13,211
-12,465
 
2006
-827,971
-71,782
-234,101
-13,528
-47,923
-20,109
-89,722
-13,584
-64,531
13,617
-15,502
-8,103
 
2007
-808,763
-68,169
-258,506
-14,877
-44,744
-20,878
-84,304
-13,161
-74,796
14,434
-12,449
-6,876
 
2008
-816,199
-78,342
-268,040
-15,209
-42,991
-20,674
-74,120
-13,400
-64,722
18,597
-11,400
-4,988
 
2009
-503,582
-21,590
-226,877
-7,743
-28,192
-14,162
-44,669
-10,604
-47,762
16,143
-9,877
-1,776
 
Source: U.S. Census Bureau,
U.S. International Trade in Goods and Services, December and Annual Revisions for 2009, Series FT-900 (10-04).


Appendix 2B: The Standard Theory

 

Comparative Advantage: Ricardo Model and Gains from Trade

 

There are two countries, Industria and Bucolia. Industria produces the manufactured good widgets; Bucolia grows cycads. For Industria it takes one man-hour to produce one widget and 2 man-hours to produce one cycad. Bucolia must devote more man-hours to produce both goods; 10 for a widget and 5 for a cycad as shown in the following table:

 

                              Unit Labor Requirement

                              Product                              

                                                Widgets     Cycads                       

     Country        Industria                1              2                           

                            Bucolia                10              5                           

                                                                          

Without trade the relative price in man-hours of widgets with respect to cycads (Pw/Pc) for each country is calculated as:

                                                           

                            W/C        

       Industria       0.5                                                     

       Bucolia          2.0

                                                           

The relative world price must lie between these country extremes; assume that it is Pw/Pc = 1.                       

                                                                          

If Industria desires 1 cycad what is the best way to get it? It can either produce it itself or it can trade for it. Producing it requires 2 units (man-hours) of labor with the following results:                                             

              

              Labor      Widgets               Cycads 

               used       produced             produced                           

                  2                  0                        1                       

                                                                          

These 2 labor units produce 1 cycad and zero widgets. Industria can, however, devote these same 2 units of labor to produce widgets instead of cycads:

 

           Labor         Widgets               Cycads                

           used           produced             produced                           

               2                    2                          0       

 

Industria uses two units of labor to produce 2 widgets. At the world price it trades one widget for one cycad with the following result:  

                                                                          

                         Labor          Widgets               Cycads                

After trade          2                  1                           1                       

 

For the same amount of labor Industria now has a widget and a cycad.

 

Bucolia also benefits from trade. If Bucolia desires 1 widget what is the best way to get it? It can either produce it itself or it can trade for it. Producing it requires 10 units (man-hours) of labor with the following results:                                                                         

                                                                          

               Labor     Widgets               Cycads                

               used       produced             produced                           

                   10             1                          0                       

                                                                          

Bucolia can, however, devote these same 10 units of labor to produce cycads instead of widgets:

              

               Labor     Widgets               Cycads                

               used       produced             produced                           

                 10               0                          2                       

 

Trading a cycad for a widget gives the following:

                                                                          

                         Labor          Widgets               Cycads                

After trade          10                1                         1                         

 

For the same amount of labor Bucolia now has a cycad and a widget. Thus each country by specializing in one good increases its total consumption.



 
The Geometry of Tariffs



 
The above figure represents the simple geometry of tariffs assuming a home country on one side and the rest of the world as the other party.
 
S: supply curve in home country; this is less than the world supply curve; It represents domestic production exclusive of imports of foreign production.
 
D: demand curve in home country; this is less than the world demand curve.
 
Po: price in absence of tariff, the price at the intersection of world supply and demand curves. These curves are not shown in the interests of simplicity; they are both off to the right on the graph.
 
Pt: home price with tariff – higher due to reduction in imports. Foreign producers receive a lower price and are therefore only willing to supply less.
 
PFt: price in foreign countries with tariff – lower because some foreign production that would have been sold to “home” is now kept in “foreign”.
 
S1: amount supplied by home producers at pre-tariff price.
 
S2: amount supplied by home producers at higher post-tariff price.
 
D1: amount demanded by home consumers at pre-tariff price.
 
D2: amount demanded by home consumers at higher post-tariff price.
 
Consumer surplus:  w+x+y+z = loss in consumer surplus due to rise in price.
 
Producer surplus: w = gain in home producer surplus due to rise in price.
 
Tariff revenue: y+g = amount of tariff (Pt – PFt) times quantity imported (D2-S2).
 
Assuming equal weights for each party the  net cost is loss in consumer surplus – gain in producer surplus – government tariff revenue: (w+x+y+z)-w-(y+g) = x+z-g.
 
Efficiency of free trade: triangle x represents the production distortion cost resulting from domestic producers producing an excess quantity of the good, triangle z represents the consumption distortion cost resulting from consumers consuming less of the good.
 

Appendix 2C: Multiple Equilibrium
 
Gomory and Baumol provide a brief outline of their multiple equilibrium model: 1) The model deviates from classical trade models only in the assumption of economies of scale. 2) It consists of a set of demand and production functions from each commodity in each country. 3) Supply and demand for each commodity are equal; there is one variable input, labor, where total revenue equals labor cost for each industry (zero economic profit); labor in each country is fully employed. The model outputs are: quantities of each good produced and consumed in each of the two countries, share of total output of each good produced by each country, quantity of labor in each country for the production of each good, price of each good, wage rate in each country and total income in each country. They also assume that labor is the only input to production; there is a fixed quantity of labor available in each country; and demand functions in each country combine into a Cobb-Douglas type national utility function. This implies that the amount spent on each product is fixed, i.e. demands are unit elastic over their full range.[1]
 
Assumptions similar to these are employed in many standard economic models to bring out the underlying factors; these are not at all eccentric or peculiar. Cobb-Douglas functions, i.e. functions of the form Q = AKxL1-x are generally used by economists owing to their convenient and easy to interpret economic properties.
 
It is the case that scale economies tend to natural monopoly or perfect specialization in each industry. The authors sketch a proof that under the assumptions of their model each such perfect specialization outcome is also an equilibrium outcome. [2] They also show that with n goods and assuming that each of the countries must have at least one industry the number of possible industry assignments to both countries total 2n – 2 specialized assignments. Thus there can be an enormous number of equilibrium points.
 
How do they calculate the points on the upper and lower boundaries? To find the upper boundary they formulate a mathematical program which maximizes national income (or utility) subject to the following three constraints: full employment in each country, quantity supplied equals quantity demanded for each product; each industry has zero (economic) profit. The lower boundary curve is calculated by minimizing national income (utility) subject to the three constraints. In practice there are a number of simplifications which render solving the problem more mathematically tractable.[3]
 
In the event of “nonspecialized” equilibrium points, i.e. industries in which production is shared by the two countries, the authors show that these are bounded by the upper frontier. However, these may fall beneath the lower specialized frontier. They show that these lower equilibrium points are unstable and conclude that the space between the boundary curves closely approximate the region of stable equilibrium points.[4]
 
They prove that under scale economies a locally stable equilibrium point can exist that does not attain productive efficiency i.e. the largest output of one commodity attainable that does not reduce the output of any of the other commodities. They conclude that the “invisible hand can indeed, by the happenstance of history find itself stuck at an equilibrium that is locally optimal but globally far inferior to others, even inferior to the autarky [that is one country monopolizes production] equilibrium for at least one of the trading countries.” In other words “some of the locally stable equilibria will keep the absolute incomes of one of the two countries, and in many cases those of both countries, below their maximal attainable levels.”[5]
 
They examine the case of linear models, i.e. those that assume constant returns to scale for all factors of production except that of land which is, of course subject to diminishing returns. They find that 1) there also exist upper and lower boundaries of the equilibria as in the case of scale economies, 2) if one country’s equilibria is at a maximum productivity for each commodity it produces, then increases in its trading partner’s productivity in one of those goods may result in the industry being lost to that country, 3) it is possible to determine the characteristics of an ideal trading partner, these being that the partner is impoverished with wages less than one-third the level of the more affluent trading country, 4) in case 3 it would benefit the more industrial country to help its low wage partner improve its trading position; however if the poorer partner’s wage is higher than a low threshold level then the richer country would lose out by that strategy. Again this is like the scale economies model.[6] If the poorer country is an aggressive potential threat then it might in the long run never be beneficial for the industrial country to help out. But of course this is beyond the purview of the economics profession.
 
These are the conditions for a country to constitute an ideal trading partner under the simulations of the linear model. “It must be a producer of a modest share of the traded commodities, leaving it with low relative wages and a small share of world income; it must be a maximally efficient producer of just those goods that it does supply; and it must be an inefficient producer of all the remaining commodities, so that it constitutes no competitive threat in those industries.” [7]
 
There is one additional conclusion to be drawn from these series of simulations. Rising productivity in industry i in the minor trading partner, country 2, benefits country 2 through a greater abundance in good i and also by a rise in the wage rate which more than compensates for the rise in prices. But the major partner, country 1, is harmed because the rise in the prices of country 2’s goods increases the cost of country 1’s imports without any increase in its purchasing power.[8]
 
Gomory and Baumol look at a number of real world conditions that add complications to their model. 1) There are in reality more than two countries. While some new features arise in the multi-country case the fundamental finding remains that there is a zone of conflict in the interests of countries similar in wealth. 2) In reality goods may be subject to diminishing returns to scale or in which after an interval of increasing returns, diminishing returns to scale sets in. These lead to the likelihood that perfectly specialized outcomes give way to multi-country production of the commodities. They extend the model to deal with the case where equilibrium points may include multi-country production. 3) They also extend the model for the case where some goods are not tradable internationally. 4) They include in their analysis the case where some industries have economies of scale while others do not. None of these cases fundamentally change the conclusions that there are inherent conflicts as well as regions of mutual gain in international trade.[9]
 
Appendix 2D: Stolper-Samuelson Theorem
 
The Stolper–Samuelson theorem is a basic theorem in Heckscher–Ohlin type trade theory. It describes a relation between real wages and real returns to capital. Under the economic assumptions of constant returns to scale, perfect competition, and an equality of the number of factors to the number of products a rise in the relative price of a good will lead to a rise in the return to that factor which is used most intensively in the production of the good. A fall in the relative price means a fall in the return to the other factor.
 
In an economy that produces only wheat and cloth, with labor and land as the factors of production, wheat is a land-intensive industry and cloth is labor-intensive.  With the usual assumption of microeconomics that the price of each product equals its marginal cost the price of cloth should be:
 
1)      Pcloth = ar + bw
2)      Pwheat = cr + dw
 
where r is rent, w is the wage; a and b are the amounts of each factor used in cloth production; c and d are the amounts of each factor used in wheat production. 
 
When cloth experiences a rise in its price, at least one of its factors must also become more expensive, for equation 1 to hold true. It can be assumed that labor, the intensively used factor in the production of cloth, is the one that would rise. Similarly, when the wage rises, rent must fall, in order for equation 2 to hold true. But a fall in rent also affects equation 1. For it to still hold true, then, the rise in wages must be more than proportional to the rise in cloth prices.
 
Thus, a rise in the price of a product will more than proportionally raise the return to the most intensively used factor, and a fall on the return to the less intensively used factor.
 
Appendix 2E: Multiplier Effect of Imports
 
The following illustrates the simple multiplier effect of trade:
 
Assume that the Marginal Propensity to Consume is
 
dC/dY  =  0.6
 
Therefore the Marginal Propensity to Save is
 
dS/dY  =  0.4
 
The multiplier is calculated as
              
1/(dS/dY)  =  2.5
 
But if dC/dY is divided into parts:
                             
1) Marginal propensity to consume domestic goods
                             
dCd/dY  =   0.5   
 
2) Marginal propensity to consume imported goods
                             
dCm/dY =  0.1   
 
The multiplier is then
                             
1/[(dS/dY) + (dCm/dY)] = 2           
                             
With a stimulus injection of $10 billion and no marginal propensity to import:
                             
Income increases by 25   billion
 
With an injection of $10 billion and with a marginal propensity to import:
                             
Income increases by only 20 billion
 
This simple analysis ignores the effect of increased imports increasing foreign incomes and hence inducing some increase in exports.


 
Appendix 2F: Trade Warfare
 
Trade warfare is illustrated in the following table:[10]

 
Problem of trade warfare
                                     Japan                   Japan
                              Free trade            Protection
 
                Free                  10                        20
     U.S.   Trade   10                         -10
              Protec-              -10                       -5
     U.S.     tion     20                          -5

 
The table shows the free trade trap as an example of a payoff matrix from the classic game-theoretic prisoner’s dilemma. Assume the payoffs from two trade policies as given in the payoff matrix. If both countries agree to follow free trade strategies the payoff to each is 10. If one chooses free trade and the other chooses protection the free trader loses 10, the protector gains 20. Minimizing the maximum loss results in both opting for protection with a loss of 5 for each. A cooperative policy through a free trade agreement improves the outcomes for both with each gaining 10.

Appendix 2G: Brander-Spencer Analysis
 
Krugman and Obstfeld present the following analysis by Brander and Spencer.[11] The latter have proposed an argument for industrial policy as illustrated in the following payoff matrices. In some industries with very large economies of scale there will be a small number of firms with excess returns that impel great international competition. A “subsidy to domestic firms, by deterring investment and production by foreign competitors, can raise the profits of domestic firms by more than the amount of the subsidy.” Assume that an American firm, Boeing and a European firm, Airbus are competing in the production of a new type of aircraft; the following are the payoffs resulting from the two strategies: produce or don’t produce.

                                                 Brander-Spencer Analysis
 
                                                             Airbus  
                                                 Produce             Don't Produce
                        Produce                    -5                         0
Boeing                                   -5                        100      
                Don't produce                 100                      0
                                                 0                           0        
                                               
 
If both firms try to produce at the same time each one loses – upper left. If Boeing obtains a small head start it will produce – upper right (Airbus would have the same advantage). However Europe can reverse that advantage with a subsidy of 25 resulting in the following.

                                                 Brander-Spencer Analysis
 
                                                             Airbus  
                                                 Produce             Don't Produce
                        Produce                    20                         0
Boeing                                   -5                        100      
                Don't produce                 125                      0
                                                 0                           0        


 
Equilibrium shifts from the upper right to the lower left. Airbus profits while Boeing is deterred from entering or leaves the industry. Airbus profit (125) far exceeds the subsidy (25).
 
On the other hand, a slight difference can change the outcome.
 

                                                 Airbus  

                                                 Produce             Don't Produce

                        Produce                    -20                         0

Boeing                                    5                        125       

                Don't produce                 100                       0

                                                 0                           0        


 
If Boeing has some advantage sufficient to keep it in the industry while Airbus is at a relative disadvantage then the latter cannot produce profitably; equilibrium is in the upper right corner. Now a subsidy of 25 would still induce Airbus to enter but profits would be less than the subsidy.
 
 
Airbus  

                                                 Produce             Don't Produce

                        Produce                     5                          0

Boeing                                    5                        125       

                Don't produce                 125                       0

                                                 0                           0        

Thus the total gain to Europe through Airbus’ profits is less than the cost to Europe of providing the subsidy. The difference is because the subsidy to Airbus is not a deterrent to the entry of Boeing.  Also such subsidies face the prospect of retaliation risking a trade war that leaves all parties worse off.
 
 


 
 
 
 


[1] Gomory and Baumol, Global Trade and Conflicting National Interests, pp. 77-81.
[2] Ibid
[3] Ibid, pp. 87-90.
[4] Ibid, pp. 91-92.
[5] Ibid, pp. 94-97.
[6] Ibid, p. 100.
[7] Ibid, p. 112.
 [8] Ibid, pp. 115-116.
[9] Ibid, pp. 117-141.
[10] Krugman and Obstfeld, International Economics, p. 217.
 [11] Ibid, pp. 261-64.

 



 

   

No comments:

Post a Comment