Sunday, August 25, 2013

Immigration Appendix


Appendix 3A

Table 1

Changing Ethnic Composition of U.S. 1960-2000

                        

 
Total
Population
White
%
Black
%
American
Indian,
Eskimo,
and Aleut
%
Asian
and
Pacific
Islander
%
1960
179,323,175
158,831,732
88.57
18,871,831
10.52
551,669
0.31
980,337
0.55
1970
203,211,926
177,748,975
87.47
22,580,289
11.11
827,255
0.41
1,538,721
0.76
1980
226,545,805
188,371,622
83.15
26,495,025
11.70
1,420,400
0.63
3,500,439
1.55
1990
248,709,873
199,686,070
80.29
29,986,060
12.06
1,959,234
0.79
7,273,662
2.92
2000
281,421,906
211,353,725
75.10
34,361,740
12.21
2,447,989
0.87
11,569,280
4.11

 

 
Mexican
%
Other Hispanic
%
Other
race
%
Hispanic
origin
(of any
race)
%
White, not
of Hispanic
origin
%
1960
 
 
 
 
87,606
 
 
 
 
 
1970
4,532,435
2.23
5,056,781
2.49
516,686
0.25
9,589,216
4.72
169,023,068
83.18
1980
8,740,439
3.86
6,296,351
2.78
6,758,319
2.98
15,036,790
6.64
180,256,366
79.57
1990
13,495,938
5.43
8,858,121
3.56
9,804,847
3.94
22,354,059
8.99
188,128,296
75.64
2000
20,640,711
7.33
14,597,770
5.19
15,436,924
5.49
35,238,481
12.52
194,514,140
69.12

Lee, Martin and Fogel, Immigrant Stock’s Share of U.S. Population Growth 1970-2004

 

Table 2

2010 Population

  Total population
308,745,538
  Hispanic or       
   Latino
50,477,594
   16.35%
Non-Hispanic White
196,817,552
     63.75%
      Black
 
37,685,848
    12.21%
      Asian
 
14,465,124
     4.69%
Other
 
9,299,420
    3.01%

 

Source: U.S. Census Bureau, 2010 Census

 

 

Table 3

Post 1970 Foreign Stock

U.S. Total
Foreign Stock Total
Foreign Stock % of Total
Growth of FS as % of Growth of Pop.
Foreign Stock: White, not Hispanic
Foreign Stock: Mexican
Foreign Stock: Other Hispanic
Foreign Stock: Black
Foreign Stock: Asian
Foreign Stock: Other
1970
203,211,926
1980
226,545,805
8,614,549
3.80%
36.92%
1,610,349
2,105,405
1,196,689
791,717
2,267,044
643,345
1990
248,709,873
19,926,534
8.01%
51.04%
1,838,476
5,700,216
3,866,493
1,869,415
5,786,066
865,869
2000
281,421,906
38,287,425
13.60%
56.13%
3,687,870
13,525,719
6,848,792
3,093,964
10,028,185
1,102,895
2004
293,645,630
45,857,158
15.62%
61.93%
4,399,345
16,208,619
8,224,327
3,710,067
11,994,610
1,320,190

 

Adapted from Lee, Martin and Fogel, Immigrant Stock’s Share of U.S. Population Growth 1970-2004

Appendix 3B

Gini Coefficient


 


The above graph shows the Lorenz curve which plots the cumulative proportion of the total income of a population. The Gini coefficient is the ratio of the area that lies between the line of perfect equality and the Lorenz curve. The line of perfect equality is the 45 degree line; if all members of the population had the same income the cumulative share would lie along this line. The Gini coefficient is the area between the line of equality and the Lorenz curve as a proportion of the total area under the line of equality. It is therefore given by G=E/(E+F) where E is the area between equality and Lorenz and F is the area under the Lorenz curve. A low Gini coefficient indicates a more equal distribution; a value of zero represents complete income equality. Higher Gini coefficients indicate more income inequality with a value of one corresponding to complete inequality. Notice that the area of the triangle underneath the line of perfect inequality is ½. Thus the Gini statistic is:
 


 
where the Lorenz curve is represented by the function Y = f(X).

Appendix 3C

Immigration and Gini Coefficients

 

I. Cross Section State Data 2010 Hispanic Population

Data Sources:

Hispanic Population: US Census Bureau

Gini: 2010 American Community Survey 1-Year Estimates

 

Regression: Gini on Percent Hispanic Population by State 2010

 

                        Constant         Hispanic %

Coefficient
0.448
0.056
S.E.
0.004
0.029
t statistic
106.760
1.926
F statistic
3.711
 
r2
0.070
 

 

II. U.S. data 1970 – 2010 Hispanic Foreign Stock

Data Sources:

Gini: US Census Bureau Current Population Survey Annual Social and Economic Supplements

Hispanic Foreign Stock interpolated annually from the following table:

Post 1970 Foreign Stock

US
Mexico
Other Hispanic
Total Hispanic
Total Population
Hispanic FS %
1970
0
0
0
203,211,926
0
1980
2,105,405
1,196,689
3,302,094
226,545,805
0.014576
1990
5,700,216
3,866,493
9,566,709
248,709,873
0.038465
2000
13,525,719
6,848,792
20,374,511
281,421,906
0.072398
2004
16,208,619
8,224,327
24,432,946
293,656,355
0.083203
2006
16,796,497
8,469,111
25,265,607
298,280,698
0.084704
2010
20,282,604
9,413,835
29,696,439
308,745,538
0.096184

 

1970 – 2004 from Lee, Martin and Fogel, Immigrant Stock’s Share of U.S. Population Growth

2006 from Martin and Fogel, Projecting the U.S. Population to 2050, unpublished calculation

2010 calculation based on 2010 Census and Martin and Fogel estimates

Regression: Gini on Percent Hispanic Post Foreign Stock 1970 – 2010

 

                              Constant         Hispanic %

Coefficient
0.395
0.873
S.E.
0.002
0.030
t statistic
251.255
29.450
F statistic
867.302
 
r2
0.957
 

 

Therefore, Gini = .395 + .873*(Hispanic FS %) and if the Hispanic percentage doubles from the 10% to 20% the Gini would rise to .57, levels characteristic of Latin America.

 

III. U.S. data 1970 – 2009 Foreign Stock, Trade Balance

Data Sources:

Gini: US Census Bureau Current Population Survey Annual Social and Economic Supplements

Foreign Stock from Appendix 3A Table 3 plus Martin and Fogel estimates

Trade Balance from U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Division

 

Regression: Gini on Percent Foreign Stock 1970 - 2009

 

                           Constant          FS %

Coefficient
0.390
0.506
S.E.
0.002
0.015
t statistic
254.733
32.664
F statistic
1066.931
 
r2
0.966
 

 

Regression: Gini on Trade Balance 1970 - 2009

 

                           Constant          TB

Coefficient
0.413
-8.7E-05
S.E.
0.003
9.49E-06
t statistic
126.504
-9.151
F statistic
83.745
 
r2
0.688
 

 

In this case the large negative trade balance causes the estimated coefficient to be very small and negative. The fit is reasonably strong but much less so than in the foreign stock regression.

 

Regression: Gini on TB and FS 1970 - 2009

 

                           Constant          TB           FS%

Coefficient
0.388
1.47E-05
0.569
S.E.
0.002
6.19E-06
0.030
t statistic
232.829
2.370
18.703
F statistic
601.113
 
r2
0.970
 

 

Multicollinearity causes the trade balance variable to have the wrong sign making the results uninterpretable.  To assess the contribution of each variable the partial correlation coefficients are computed:


Partial correlation between Gini and foreign stock holding trade balance constant = 0.951

Partial correlation between Gini and trade balance holding foreign stock constant = 0.363

 

Thus holding the trade balance constant the foreign stock is still highly significant. Holding the foreign stock constant the trade balance is somewhat significant. The conclusion is that immigration has the largest effect on income inequality.

 

Appendix 3D

Immigration Surplus

 

The following graph represents the economic analysis of the benefits of immigration:

 
 
W1: Wage at time 1

Q1: Quantity of labor demanded at time 1

W2: Wage at time 2 following high immigration

Q2:  Quantity of labor demanded at time 2

 

The area of the triangle under the demand curve and above the line W1-A represents the labor market surplus at time 1. The area of the triangle under the demand curve and above the line W2-C represents the labor market surplus at time 2.  The surplus due to immigration is represented by triangle ABC. The size of the immigration surplus depends on the steepness of the demand curve. A horizontal line representing an infinite demand for labor means that there would be no immigrant surplus for the native population. The evidence indicates that, in fact, there is at least some immigrant surplus but it goes to the employers of immigrants. Even so the immigrant surplus is far outweighed by all of the other costs of immigration.




 

Appendix 3E


Regression Model: Impact of Immigration on State and Local Expenditures

 

There are two important ways in which immigration may affect expenditures. First there is the interaction between immigration and the welfare state. Immigrants and their offspring have a demand for social services, including; welfare, medical assistance and housing as do native born immigrants. However, the higher level of poverty among recent immigrants has a greater impact than is the case for the population as a whole. Similarly, immigrants have the same need for education as do other population groups. However, a higher level of poverty leads to a higher reliance on public education. Cultural and language differences require additional and, often expensive, compensatory programs. The second impact of immigration is due to the effects on spending for infrastructure and the quality of life. Congestion and environmental effects due to the increase in population creates the demand for additional public spending. Maintaining public safety and the quality of life requires large increases in expenditures. Public utilities and transportation facilities are severely impacted by an increasing population. In addition, the most recent immigrant cohorts appear to have a higher need for police, fire and public transportation than the general population magnifying the effect on public spending. Furthermore, the higher level of poverty in recent immigrant groups also means that these groups have less tax paying ability and, therefore, impose a higher tax burden on the general population.

 

Estimation Procedure:

It is expected that certain expenditures are more likely to be sensitive to immigration. Anticipated sensitive categories are education, medical, social services, public safety, environment and infrastructure. Expenditures for administration, pensions, social insurance, debt service etc. are excluded. It seems likely that the impact of immigration on the latter would be indirect and not out of proportion to the percent of immigrants within the population. An attempt is made throughout the study to, if anything, understate the estimated impacts.

 

A linear regression model was specified. Expenditures for each category are regressed on populations for various cohorts of the foreign born and offspring of recent immigrants; as well as age groups of the white and black populations. The coefficients obtained are a direct measure of the proportion of expenditures allocated to increases in each group. A preliminary examination of the data raises two issues to be addressed. In the first place, a time series analysis is inadequate for data provided by the Census Bureau.  A feasible approach is to look at a cross section made up of recent data presented for the 50 states. Furthermore, a simple regression combining all the states into one dataset would obscure the results since there are different political cultures and institutional arrangements among the states. Therefore, a set of regional dummy variables was specified to group states into those with similar attitudes or needs regarding public assistance, environment, transportation etc.

 

The estimated coefficients from the model were used to calculate the impact of the immigrant groups on each expenditure category. The impacts for each category were summed giving totals for each state. Using the percentage of the foreign born cohorts, a crude estimate of the net impacts after tax receipts, were obtained. Applying per capita income data then refined these crude estimates.

 

Model

 

X = C + D + w1 PNHW<18 + w2 PNHW18-45 + w3 PNHW45<  + b1PB<18 + b2 PB18-45 + b3 PB45< 

       +  f1 PFB90-00 + f2 PFB80-90 + f3 PFB<80 +  f4 PNBO

where,

X: Expenditures in $thousands for one of these categories: education, education capital, welfare, hospitals, health, public safety, housing, environment; years 1992, 1999

C: Constant term measures the level of the Northeast effect

D: Dummy variables: South, North, Midwest, West, Pacific measured as a deviation from the constant, C representing the northeast states.

P’s: Population numbers for

       Ethnic groups – Non-Hispanic Whites, Blacks, Foreign-born, Other

       NHW and Black broken into following age groups: <18, 18-45, 45<

       FB broken into year of entry: <80, 80-90, 90-2000      

w’s: coefficients for white cohorts

b’s: coefficients for black cohorts

f’s: coefficients for foreign cohorts

 

Estimating the coefficients for each expenditure category began with running an initial regression on the full series of independent variables. Variables were discarded for two reasons. In the first place, it was obvious that a “displacement” effect was present. This effect caused the appearance of anomalous negative coefficients for certain variables. This could be caused by the inter-state migration of certain groups. For example, an older population, e.g. whites, may displace a younger one making it appear as if there is a negative impact on education. Alternatively if a young immigrant cohort moves in and older whites move out this may cause a negative correlation and make it appear as if immigration depresses spending on health. A more important effect was probably due to the extreme multicollinearity within group age or time cohorts. One variable in each of the three age cohorts within a population category would “soak up” all the explanatory power due to that group. The strategy followed was to eliminate the negative coefficients due to multicollinearity and displacement effects. In a number of instances, non-significant coefficients were kept or inserted for the white or black population, which diminished the relative impact of the immigrant contingent. This was one more way of keeping the estimates of the immigrant impact conservative.  On the other hand, in every category significant coefficients for immigrant variables would always be found; these were usually highly significant. High R2 values were expected and observed; large populations will engender high spending. The crucial measures to look at are the coefficients of the various population groups relative to each other.

 

Education

XEDU = -1,615,922 DSOUTH + 7.393 PNHW<18 + 5.087 PB<18 + 6.993 PFB90-00 +. 866 PNBO

             (-2.786)                (13.528)            (3.261)           (7.407)             (2.524)

R2 = .9901

Education Capital

XEDC = -167,240 + 213,534 DPACIFIC + 170,230DWEST + 79,848 DMIDWEST + 84,923 DNORTH  + 

                 (-1.979)    (1.424)                 (1.608)                  (.728)                        (.611)

            .867PNHW<18 + 1.158PB<18 +.253PFB90-00 + .265 PNBO

            (8.595)           (4.021)        (1.449)           (4.177)

R2 = .9750

Welfare

XWEL = 852,663 - 1,877,880 DWEST  - 2,208,927 DNORTH  - 1,612,748 DSOUTH   

             (1.167)    (-2.204)                  (-1.795)                    (-1.736)

          + 3.569 PNHW<18 + 1.470 PB<18 + 4.747 PFB90-00

           (3.954)                 (0.586)          (4.526)

R2  = .8975

 

Hospitals

XHOS = 554,193DPACIFIC + 416,653DWEST + 568,527DMIDWEST + 568,803DSOUTH

             (1.302)                (1.490)                (1.805)                     (1.977)

       + .151 PNHW45< + 4.024 PB45<  + 1.821 PFB90-00                        

         (0.840)             (5.203)           (6.066)

 R2  = .8957

Health

XHEA = 497,463 DPACIFIC + 471,124 DNORTH  +  .418 PNHW45<  +  .061 PB45< + 1.416 PFB80-90            

             (2.582)                    (2.775)                  (6.002)               (.152)            (9.291)

R2   = .9602

Public Safety

XPS = -265,116 DMIDWEST  - 505,236 DSOUTH + 1.243 PNHW18-45  +  2.029 PB<18    + 5.050 PFB80-90

              (-1.253)                  (-2.404)                         (10.032)                               (3.160)            (6.092)

R2   = .9924

Housing

XHOU = 130,055 – 208,969 DWEST  - 150,060 DMIDWEST  - 176,939 DNORTH  - 240,036 DSOUTH

             (2.004)    (-2.713)               (-1.702)                  (-1.631)                (-3.015)

+ .193 PNHW18-45     +.291PB45<   +    1.037 PFB80-90

  (4.034)                 (1.144)             (11.445)

R2   = .9594

Environment, Utilities and Infrastructure

XENV  = 1,968,325DPACIFIC + 2.256PNHW18-45   + 1.988 PB45< + 11.646 PFB90-00

               (1.394)                  (3.771)                  (.642)           (9.664)

R2   = .9601

 

It is possible that for spending on environment, infrastructure and housing a density factor may cause the immigration effect to appear larger than it in fact is. The immigrant contingent tends to settle in more densely populated urban and suburban areas, magnifying the effect of congestion on these variables. These expenditures may also be extremely sensitive to increases in population. The rate of population growth, in addition to the level of the population, is a factor in these expenditures. Immigration is the major source of population increase in the U.S. Health expenditures may also be sensitive to the rate of growth accounting for the large immigrant coefficients relative to the other groups. In every equation at least one immigrant coefficient was significant with t statistics ranging from 1.449 to 11.445. For whites one insignificant coefficient was inserted; for blacks three insignificant coefficients were left in the equations. The pre 1980 foreign-born cohort did not make it into any equation; this may be an indicator of the changing characteristics of the immigrant flow. The coefficients, being derivatives of a linear function, are a measure of the marginal impact on expenditures of each variable.

Appendix 3F
Regression Model: Impact of Immigration on Mortgage Foreclosures


The following data set was used:

                      Foreclosure       Rustbelt          % Hispanic

                        Rate                                          Foreign Stock

Alabama              0.0383%              0             1.254%

Alaska                 0.0582%               0             1.581%

Arizona               0.5264%               0             13.002%

Arkansas              0.0893%              0             2.647%

California            0.7595%              0             23.520%

Colorado             0.2153%              0             7.152%

Connecticut        0.1246%              0             4.120%

Delaware             0.0919%              0             2.805%

DC                        0.2274%               0             6.441%

Florida                 0.5000%               0             13.967%

Georgia               0.2175%               0             4.825%

Hawaii                 0.0655%               0             0.958%

Idaho                   0.1203%               0             4.490%

Illinois                 0.2038%               1             9.826%

Indiana                 0.1888%              1             2.081%

Iowa                    0.0501%               0             1.909%

Kansas                 0.0591%               0             4.551%

Kentucky              0.0651%              0             1.034%

Louisiana             0.0336%              0             1.542%

Maine                  0.0333%               0             0.236%

Maryland             0.1379%              0             3.762%

Massachusetts   0.0887%              0             3.935%

Michigan             0.3000%              1             1.548%

Minnesota           0.0927%              0             1.999%

Mississippi           0.0187%              0             0.800%

Missouri               0.1410%              0             1.118%

Montana             0.0308%              0             0.330%

Nebraska             0.0490%              0             3.880%

Nevada               1.0386%               0             13.840%

New Hampshire 0.1092%              0             0.885%

New Jersey         0.1841%              0             10.097%

New Mexico       0.0566%              0             10.374%

New York            0.0686%              0             9.766%

North Carolina   0.1095%              0             4.414%

North Dakota     0.0140%              0             0.364%

Ohio                    0.2236%               1             0.635%

Oklahoma           0.0837%              0             3.225%

Oregon               0.1136%               0             6.085%

Pennsylvania       0.0895%              1             1.036%

Rhode Island       0.1217%              0             7.347%

South Carolina   0.0673%              0             1.913%

South Dakota     0.0119%              0             0.554%

Tennessee           0.1692%              0             1.739%

Texas                   0.1132%               0             15.987%

Utah                    0.1706%               0             5.413%

Vermont              0.0058%              0             0.303%

Virginia                0.1609%              0             3.848%

Washington        0.1136%              0             4.785%

West Virginia      0.0049%              0             0.209%

Wisconsin            0.0866%              1             2.081%

Wyoming             0.0235%              0             1.514%
 
Source:

Foreclosure Rate: RealtyTrac® (realtytrac.com) August 2008 U.S. Foreclosure Market Report and Total Housing Units, July 1, 2008 from US Census Bureau, Population Estimates Program T2 Housing Unit Estimates

% Hispanic Foreign Stock: US Census Bureau, GCT-T1 Population Estimates Data Set: 2008                   
Population Estimates and Martin and Fogel, Projecting the U.S. Population to 2050, FAIR, 2006

 

Regression: FR on RD and HFS 1970 - 2009

                           Constant          RD           HFS

Coefficient
0.000121
0.000894
0.028117
S.E.
0.000269
0.000576
0.003866
t statistic
0.448431
1.551382
7.272305
F statistic
26.64139
 
r2
0.526079
 

 

The results are summarized in the following equation:

 

FR = .0001 + .0009RD + .0281HFS

                         (1.55)       (7.27)

R2 = 0.53

 

FR: foreclosure rate for each state = Total Foreclosures August 2008 from RealtyTrac® (realtytrac.com) divided by Total Housing Units, July 1, 2008 from US Census Bureau, Population Estimates Program T2 Housing Unit Estimates

 

RD: rustbelt dummy variable representing the difference between the states with depressed industries (PA, OH, IN, IL, MI, WI) and the remaining states

 

HFS: Hispanic Foreign Stock from the FAIR demographic projections for 2006 divided by the July 1, 2008 CB GCT-T1. Population Estimates for each state

           

The HFS coefficient is highly significant while the RD coefficient is somewhat significant (10% level).  A 1 percent increase in Hispanic foreign stock implies a 2.8% rate of increase in the foreclosure rate (not the foreclosure rate percentage as such). The rustbelt states have a .09 percent foreclosure differential. The R2 of .53 is a fairly high fit for cross section data.  Regressing the foreclosure rate on the % Hispanic foreign stock without the rustbelt variable yields a slightly lower R2 of .502 indicating that most of the explanatory power is due to the immigrant population.

 

No comments:

Post a Comment