Complacency of Wealth
A signpost on the road to ruin for an economically
powerful nation is the self-satisfaction and complacency resulting from great
wealth. Some characteristics of what Porter defines as the wealth-driven stage
of competitive development is an ebbing of rivalry, a loss of risk taking and enterprises
run by stewards instead of entrepreneurs. “The driving force is … the wealth
that has already been achieved. The problem is that an economy driven by past
wealth is not able to maintain its wealth. This is because, most importantly,
the motivations of investors, managers and individuals shift in ways that
undermine sustained investment and innovation, and hence upgrading.”[116]
In the wealth-driven stage a nation may have lofty social goals but the
industries that remain no longer provide sufficient comparative advantage to
support rising living standards. On the other hand there tends to be a class of
rentiers and managers of companies with great market power who continue to live
well off of accumulated past wealth.[117]
The current prosperity of a wealthy nation may not be an
accurate reflection of a deteriorating economic condition. “Declining
industries may even reap record profits during the years in which they
liquidate their competitive positions by outsourcing production, cutting
investment, and milking accumulated brand equity.”[118]
In strictly economic terms, there is no negative judgment regarding the choice
made to enjoy wealth in the present despite future adverse consequences.
“Within the rigorously logical (albeit perverse) assumptions of mainstream
economics, it is merely a mathematical curiosity that free trade can make a
nation worse off by seducing it into decadent consumption. It wanted a
short-term consumption binge; it got what it wanted; what’s not to like?”[119]
The American economy has been propped up by a series of
financial asset bubbles which have provided a positive wealth effect to
consumer spending. The end of the regime
of fixed exchange rates and the ease of international capital flows have helped
to disguise the nation’s worsening economic condition. This condition is
characterized, not so much by fewer available jobs, but by a reduction in their
quality: wages and working conditions.
The modern financial system has been instrumental in
helping the U.S.
to postpone the day of reckoning by allowing the running of a large trade
deficit for a lengthy period. The asset bubbles that have occurred since the
1990s, dot com stocks, derivatives, hedge funds, junk bonds and real estate
helped the U.S.
pay for imports. Asian sovereign funds and OPEC members now own trillions of
dollars in U.S.
assets. The Taiwan
central bank, the Bank of Japan and the Abu Dhabi Investment Authority have
been bailing out Wall Street. Citigroup received $17.4 billion from sovereign
funds, much of it from Abu Dhabi .
Merrill Lynch was bailed out by Korea
and Kuwait .
From March 2007 to June 2008 these Asian and OPEC funds have funneled $36
billion to the Street. China
has also recently cultivated a close relationship with the Blackstone Group. China
will presumably learn from this hedge fund specialist some very sophisticated
investment strategies.[120]
All of these wonders of international finance are courtesy of the same folks
who enabled the great subprime meltdown and who are indifferent to issues of
economic security; many of these foreign interests are not necessarily reliable
friends.
American complacency goes back to the early postwar era.
In the 1950s America
felt no threat from possible emerging economic competitors. “The United States would always enjoy a trade surplus
with Japan , Secretary of
State John Foster Dulles said in 1955, because Japan ’s products were so inferior.”[121] This attitude is one more example of the
arrogance that has characterized free traders for almost two centuries. America
here was simply following the British precedent of the 19th century
which on becoming the richest, most powerful economy in the world “renounced
old protectionist habits.”[122]
The 19th century British precedent is an
instructive example of the complacency that can set in with economic
leadership. Britain ’s
political and business leadership naively expected the rest of the world to
compliantly follow their free trade example. Other nations refused to
subordinate themselves to Britain ’s
trade ideology; after the 1860s protectionism became the chosen policy for most
of Europe .
Two nations in particular, the U.S.
and Germany forged ahead
under protectionist policies while Britain lagged under free trade.
From 1870 to 1913 U.S. industrial
production surged by 4.7% annually; Germany ’s
advanced at an annual average of 4.1% while Britain ’s rate was half at 2.1%. Britain
held its lead for two decades after adopting free trade but the protectionist
nations eventually caught up. Fletcher notes the effects of this economic
complacency:
But
despite the mounting failure of its great strategic gamble, Britain stuck to free trade abroad
and laissez-faire absence of industrial policy at home. Fundamentally, the
country was lulled by the Indian summer of its industrial supremacy … into thinking
that free trade was optimal as a permanent policy. The clarity of British
thinking was not helped by the fact that certain vested interests had fattened
upon free trade and established a grip upon the levers of power that was hard
to break.[123]
American leadership today suffers from same the illusory
belief in the enduring advantages to be derived from free trade.
The American leadership’s blind belief in the free trade
ideology is accompanied by an indifference to manufacturing. Such was also the
case with 17th century Spain . In the 16th
century Spain was the
leading political and economic power in Europe .
Spain ’s
mercantilism required that the inhabitants of its vast empire buy only from
Spanish producers. However, eventually Spanish merchants, impatient for quick
profits simply gave their own brand names to the products of foreign suppliers.
A Spaniard in 1675 remarked “Let London manufacture those fabrics of hers to
her heart’s content; Holland her chambrays; Florence her cloth; the Indies their beaver and vicuna; Milan her brocades; Italy
and Flanders their linens, so long as our
Capitol can enjoy them. The only thing it proves is that all nations train
journeymen for Madrid and that Madrid is the queen of
Parliaments, for all the world serves her and she serves nobody.” Today such
folly is still heard regarding trade theory and the BOP deficit. After all it
is said that the Asians “are giving us useful things in exchange for paper with
the portrait of George Washington.”[124]
With the Spanish not having to actually make things
anymore, other nations picked up the slack and attained the skills necessary
for the growth of industry. At the same time Spain entered upon its long
decline:
The
prevalent hidalgo mentality looked upon imports more as a source of pride than a
latent danger for the country’s economy.
… With such ideas prevailing … it is not surprising that in 1659 … France obtained the right to introduce into Catalonia all kinds of duty-free products, and … in 1667,
the Spanish frontiers were opened to England . “One observer noted that “Spain supplies itself from other countries with
almost all things which are manufactured for common use and which consist in
the industry and toil of man … With typical perceptiveness, a Venetian
ambassador remarked, “Spain
cannot exist unless relieved by others, nor can the rest of the world exist
without the money of Spain .”[125]
With the diminishment of the production of precious
metals from the New World mines Spain ’s
century of prosperity came to an end. During that time many had abandoned their
land. Instead “schools had multiplied,
but they had served mostly to produce a half-educated intellectual proletariat
who scorned productive industry and manual labor and found positions in the
bloated state bureaucracy which served above all to disguise unemployment. Spain
in the seventeenth century lacked entrepreneurs and artisans but had an
overabundance of bureaucrats, lawyers, priests, beggars, and bandits.”[126] This description of 17th century Spain is uncannily similar to that of 21st
century America .
In the 18th century Spain ’s
neighbor on the Iberian Peninsula, Portugal , also found its infant
manufacturing industries aborted by English competitors. One Portuguese
nobleman lamented that “two-thirds of our necessities are now supplied by England .
The English produce, sell, and resell everything which is needed in our
country. The ancient manufactures of Portugal have been destroyed.” Port
wine and gold from Brazil
paid for these English goods.[127]
Ironically it was the exchange of Portuguese wine for British cloth that helped
Ricardo to construct his original theory of comparative advantage.
The fate of the great mercantile and industrial
city-states of Italy , Venice , Florence and Genoa is one more
instructive example of the dangers of losing out in the competition for
manufacturing. These cities had pioneered much of the financial and
manufacturing innovations that transformed the economy of Europe
during the late middle ages and Renaissance. But they were passed by with the
opening of the great Atlantic trade routes as well as by obsolete guild and
political restrictions. Cipolla points to the contribution of foreign trade to Italy ’s
decline:
What
had happened to Italy
is a good example of the ambivalence of foreign trade. From the eleventh to the
sixteenth centuries foreign trade had been indeed an ‘engine of growth’ for
Italy because (a) it provided the
country with raw materials and commodities for re-export and (b) it augmented
the demand for manufactures, thus stimulating the growth of craft skills and
manufacturing production. From the beginning of the seventeenth century … the
structure of foreign trade changed completely. Foreign manufactures were
brought in and drove Italian products and their manufacturers out of the
market. At the same time foreign demand favored the production of oil, wine and
raw silk. One may argue that in the short run Italy derived from this new
arrangement some comparative advantages of the kind illustrated by the
Ricardian theory. In the long run, however, foreign trade acted as ‘engine of
decline’: it contributed to shift both capital and labor from the secondary and
tertiary sectors to agriculture. In regard to labor this shift meant, in the
long run, a) the reduction in number of both the literate craftsmen and the
enterprising merchants, b) the growth in size of the illiterate peasantry, and
c) the rise in power of the landed nobility. … The cities lost their previous
vitality. The great Universities of Padua and Bologna slipped into oblivion. … Italy had begun her career as an underdeveloped
area within Europe .[128]
The unfortunate economic histories of the Iberian and
Italian peninsulas provide a chilling warning to those who believe that
manufacturing is not all that important.
American Business
Culture
American manufacturing is a sector that has suffered
greatly from poor planning and the short-term orientation. As Porter observed some twenty years ago:
American
firms have been slow to adopt new process technologies. Slow to upgrade
facilities, and slow in introducing new products and features. Japan ,
in particular, is filing a growing share of patents, including those important
patents that are frequently cited. Overall, non-Americans were awarded 47.1
percent of all U.S.
patents awarded in 1988, the highest in history. Japanese firms are
technological leaders in such important fields as advanced manufacturing
technology, new materials, and important areas of electronics. America still creates much science and
technology but lags in translating it into competitive U.S. industries.[129]
Of course, it may well be the case that America ’s eroding advantage in patents is a
result of the failure outlined above of U.S. government officials to
protect American intellectual property rights.
The automobile industry is a paradigm of the failures of
American business in the late 20th century. Some of this can be
blamed on labor but much of it was the result of complacency, lack of judgment,
short term thinking and over reliance on government support.[130] The aircraft industry, Boeing in particular,
is another case of short term thinking. Boeing has been acquiring much of its
needed component parts in Europe, Japan
and, lately, China .
Boeing now realizes that this strategy has not worked out well and is trying to
bring its manufacturing back inside the U.S. The question is whether our
manufacturing has been so hollowed out that tariff assistance will be required
for such strategies to succeed. Even GE’s Immelt admitted that real engineering
is being traded for financial engineering.[131]
However, financial engineering is another activity that can be outsourced
abroad as well as in-sourced via immigration. A further irony, as will be seen
in a subsequent chapter, financial engineering has been enlisted in support of
social engineering, another factor which has helped to undermine the U.S.
economy.
Such financial engineering as well as high-end technical
and design services were, according to the free trade chorus, supposed to be
reserved for America ’s
knowledge-based post-industrial economy. But for some reason it isn’t quite working
out that way. “Among sophisticated business functions, product development,
including software development, is now the second-largest corporate function
being offshored. Offshoring of sophisticated white-collar tasks such as
finance, accounting, sales and personnel management is growing at 35 percent
per year.” [132]
Yet another characteristic of American business culture
is its disunity as opposed to Asian business solidarity. Thus U.S. “companies
frequently bid against each other overseas, even over sensitive long-term issues
such as technology transfer. Among other things, this makes them exceptionally
easy for foreigners to manipulate. When, for example, Japanese companies form
alliances with them, this tends to neutralize them as opponents of Japanese
trade practices.” Their dependence on these foreign allies causes many American
businesses to become virtual lobbyists promoting foreign trade policies even at
the expense of U.S.
economic interests.[133]
Law and Regulation
It is, of course, up to legislators and regulators to
protect U.S.
economic interests. Many U.S.
businesses are trying the best they can to survive and prosper on a less than
level playing-field. When foreign companies are given special trade protections
and subsidies and U.S.
companies are thrown on the global markets bare of such protection their
leadership is literally forced to make alliances with, and promote the
interests of, foreign entities.
Law and regulation has a number of aspects that require
intelligent implementation and not dogmatic application. On the one hand U.S.
deregulation has unleashed much beneficial innovation. But foreign companies
often gain important skills and expertise in product development and
manufacturing under a regime of stricter regulations and higher standards.[134]
The automobile industry is the prime example. Japanese auto makers had to learn
how to produce higher quality and greater mileage cars at a time when
complacent U.S.
companies assumed that the industry would never have to change.
However, in the area of product liability greater
American litigiousness relative to that of other nations has been a great
disadvantage. “The risk of lawsuits is so great, and the consequences so
potentially disastrous, that the inevitable result is for more caution in
product innovation than in other advanced nations.”[135]
Anti-trust is an area of law and regulation that has
affected and been affected by trade policy. Global trade reduces the
effectiveness of American antitrust laws. In foreign countries governments
encouraged and even designed cartels. Globalization is facilitating the rapid
cartelization of entire industries. An
example is the U.S.
beef packing industry. Four giant global corporations now dominate the
meatpacking industry and between 1994 and 2005 more than 122,000 cattle ranches
closed or left the industry. Suppliers of agricultural inputs have become
highly concentrated and markets for livestock and grain are dominated by a
handful of agribusinesses.[136] In 1982 a path for corporate assaults was
cleared with a Court decision striking down state anti-takeover laws. Wall Street corporate raiders were unleashed
and investment banks went into the M&A and takeover business on a large scale.
Billions were diverted from productive purposes; investment in R&D that
would have helped U.S.
companies compete in international markets was reduced.[137] This triumph of financial manipulation over
manufacturing development occurred at the very time that the Chinese began to
enter the world economic arena.
American Foreign
Policy and Free Trade
One selling point for allowing foreign nations unfair
trading advantages is the beneficial effects on U.S. foreign policy interests,
world peace and democracy. Under the postwar Pax Americana the U.S.
provided the following economic services to its allies: by keeping its economy
open to imports it encouraged world trade; the dollar was maintained as the
global currency enabling trade and international investment; security was
provided and crises managed so that disruptive political and economic threats
were controlled. It was taken for
granted that the overwhelming military and economic power of the U.S. would
continue indefinitely. But with the passage of time globalization has
increasingly upended this U.S.
dominated international system.[138]
Although, at times, free trade may induce foreign
governments to cooperate with the United States it also shifts resources to
nations, like Saudi Arabia and Venezuela, whose elites support terrorism or
subversion and China which has become an increasingly powerful adversary. U.S. presidents have deferred
pushing enforcement against the inflow of illegal goods in order to obtain
Chinese assistance with other matters such as North Korean nukes or Treasury
bond purchases. Similarly, NAFTA was unable to induce Mexico to help curtail its illegal immigration
to the U.S. [139]
World peace, democracy and human rights are other tenuous
purported benefits resulting from free trade. In the 19th century
free trade Britain
fought more wars than anyone else. However, postwar protectionist Japan has been more peaceful than free trade America .
Fletcher points out the fallacies in such contentions:
In
reality, free trade sometimes dampens international conflict and sometimes
exacerbates it. It enriches belligerent autocrats and helps them dodge
democratic reforms. Today it strengthens the Chinese military… Neither does
free trade promote human rights. If China had to rely upon domestic
demand to drive its economy, locking up its population as factory slaves would
not be such a viable strategy. The same goes in other nations, and free trade
agreements then frustrate attempts to impose sanctions on human rights
violators.[140]
However, there may be certain instances where a free
trade agreement with genuinely friendly nations may be worth the slight costs
imposed; trade policy should be flexible, not rigid.
Free Trade and the
Elite
The attitude of the current American elite toward their
middle and working class countrymen is neatly encapsulated in Obama’s famous
guns and religion speech given to elite San Franciscans. They have no sympathy
for the concerns of ordinary Americans in rustbelt states such as Pennsylvania or Ohio
regarding the displacement of jobs due to trade or immigration; indeed they do
not even understand this on an intellectual level. From the safety of their
wealth and their status, members of the elite are bewildered as to how anyone
can possibly be concerned with such matters.
However, it was not always so; presidents from Eisenhower
through Reagan generally protected the economic and national security interests
of the United States
from being undermined by foreign trade. Beginning with President George H.W.
Bush successive administrations have allowed the nation to slip into a
trap. Growing U.S. dependence on other nations
for energy, technology and even food is one result of the policies of this
trans-national elite. [141]
The political environment in this age of the global elite
provides numerous opportunities for influence peddling. The insatiable need for
contributions to fund increasingly costly political campaigns has opened the
doors to corporations and foreign interests lacking allegiance to the U.S. For
example Chinese diplomats, along with banks and corporations doing business in China , are able
to exert influence at congressional hearings, think tank briefings and public
policy events.[142]
The selling out of national interests reaches deep into
the political structure. Attempts of state politicians to fulfill their pledge
not to raise taxes have created a number of openings for foreign interests.
Indiana Governor Daniels in 2005 moved to put up the Indiana toll road for lease with the
assistance of Goldman Sachs and the Federal Highway Administration. The winner was an Australian/Spanish
consortium. With the rise of investment banks and hedge funds as profitable new
venues for the elite, advising governments on and arranging for the sale of
public assets has been added to such other endeavors as engaging in corporate
takeovers and restructurings. Goldman was paid $20 million for its supposedly
sage advice. However, opponents of the project obtained information that a sale
of an asset for $3.85 billion would produce $121 billion in revenues over the
75 year lease period.[143]
This works out to a yield for the consortium of 42%, assuming equal revenues for each of the years; a real
sweetheart deal courtesy of the local taxpayers.
In Texas Governor Perry also tried to provide for an
expanding population without increasing taxes. Ironically the Mexican
immigration that is so beloved of Perry and the Texas business elite is the source of that
expanding population. As part of the NAFTA superhighway (see NAFTA Highway and North American Union above) he proposed
the Trans Texas Corridor under which the state would take more than half a
million acres of land to build 4,000 miles of roads at a cost of between $145
and $185 billion. Two of these corridors would connect directly to a system of
Mexican roads and railroads that “would speed the movement of freight from
three deep-water ports in southwest Mexico being built by Wal-Mart and
Chinese interests.” The Corridor
advocates ultimately admitted that this “NAFTA Superhighway” was intended to
speed the flow of imported goods from Mexico
and Asia into the inland and eastern United States .[144]
Indeed the financial company advisors and brokers for
such deals, such as Goldman, Bank of America, Blackstone and Citi find it
enormously profitable to please their Chinese clients. They bring with them a
unique knowledge of and influence within the U.S. political system. And for
doing so the leadership of these banks and hedge funds are paid enormous
salaries; in 2005 the top ten hedge fund managers were paid more than $7
billion. They are also well positioned to take advantage of loopholes to
minimize taxes. Some of these multibillionaires, such as Peter Peterson, a
hedge fund founder, are ironically great advocates for ‘shared sacrifice’. They
have also persuaded Congress and administrations to exempt them from reporting
on their activities despite the enormous influence they have on the national
and global economy.[145]
They also wield great influence within the regulatory agencies (the role of the
agencies will be discussed in a subsequent chapter). The myopic investment
policies of these funds in favor of short-term results divert capital from
long-term production into short-term speculative activities.
The nexus of influence of the bankers and hedge funds
reaches the highest levels of government and transcends party lines. One time
Goldman Sachs executives holding positions in the Bush administration include
chief of staff Josh Bolton, Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson and World Bank
president Robert Zoellick. Democrats connected with Goldman include Robert
Rubin and Richard Gephardt who was employed by Goldman to work on public
finance issues. Gephardt was once a rather loud champion of protecting American
manufacturing and its workers. Another financial facilitator of foreign
economic interests is Peter Peterson of Blackstone, a chairman of the Council
on Foreign Relations. Others involved in these activities included Henry
Kissinger, Alexander Haig, former ambassador to China James Sasser and national
security advisors Brent Scowcroft and Sandy Berger. Members of the Bush family,
Prescott Bush and Neil Bush have business relations with China ; George H.W. Bush along with Bill Clinton
have been well paid for speeches given in China . The leadership of many major
American corporations have also been co-opted by the Chinese. When the small
and medium sized members of the National Association of Manufacturers pushed a
resolution calling for direct action against Chinese currency manipulation the
larger corporate members killed it.[146]
Former ambassadors have become lobbyists for the very nations they were once
posted to. Saudi Arabia and China
are particularly notable for employing this squad of one-time diplomats.
Fletcher reports that between 1972 and 1990 “fully half
the American trade diplomats who left government service went to work for
foreign nations.” One of their chief diplomatic activities has been to bribe
foreign nations to join the elite vision of a rules based trading system under
the WTO, despite the latter’s anti-American actions. “Unfortunately, this bribe
has mainly consisted in letting foreign nations run surpluses against us. We
have thus become the global buyer of last resort and the subsidizer of a system
that in theory needs no subsidy because it supposedly benefits everyone.” This means
the U.S.
spends a lot of energy trying to open up various foreign markets for our
neo-mercantilist competitors.[147]
The growth in the salaries of top corporate executives
and lobbyists constitutes a perpetual temptation for many one-time public
servants to serve something other than the public interest.[148] This is a particularly acute problem when it
came to the Wall Street firms and its financial regulators. The Patent Office,
the supposed protector of intellectual property, has too many high positions filled
by unqualified political appointees; there is a 30% turnover rate and
demoralization of remaining long time employees.[149] Such politicization and demoralization is
also the case with other financial regulators such as the SEC and Federal
Reserve Bank of New York
as we will see in a subsequent chapter.
Free Trade and National Security
The degrading of U.S. national security is an
important externality resulting from trade.
In the early 1990s a Chinese company proposed a joint venture to
McDonnell Douglas for the production of civilian passenger airplanes; bundled
in was the purchase of unique machine tools for the manufacture of advanced
aircraft and missiles. McDonnell received a transfer license from Commerce in
1994. Once the machine tools were in China the joint venture proposal
was dropped and the machine tools were diverted to a missile factory. McDonnell
Douglas was indicted in 1999 for falsifying information on the license
application and was fined. Similarly Hughes Electronics and Loral Space Systems
transferred missile technology and expertise to China greatly improving Chinese
missile capability. In 1995 the Chinese were allowed to purchase Magnequench, a
GM subsidiary which produces specially designed magnets for precision-guided
munitions. China has, in effect, acquired the
Defense Department contract to produce motors for smart bombs. When China relocated the Magnequench facility out of
the U.S.
and with their previous acquisition two other magnet producers, they became the
sole source of a vital weapon component.[150] Indeed the security concern may extend much
further. According to a senior government analyst the Magnequench technology
has another use. "It enables them to produce super-high-quality rare-earth
magnets/ring magnets for use in gas centrifuges to produce nuclear-weapons
material. And in addition to enhancing their own nuclear-weapons program we
know that China has already
proliferated ring magnets to Pakistan ,
which played a critical role in developing Pakistan 's nuclear weapons." In
February 1996 the Washington Times reported that the CIA "has uncovered
new evidence China has
violated U.S.
antiproliferation laws by exporting nuclear-weapons technology to Pakistan ."
Congress later confirmed that Chinese companies had sold 5,000 ring magnets to Pakistan .[151]
This common practice of outsourcing strategic technology
is at the point where in 2006 a consortium of ammunition producers report that
71 out of 302 critical items had just one supplier; 10% of U.S. ammunition components come
from 13 different countries. Thus, a
guaranteed supply of parts or weapons needed for national defense is no longer
possible. Chinese government hackers have also repeatedly penetrated computers
of U.S.
corporations, banks, utilities, agencies and even the Pentagon. Yet the federal
government buys computers that rely on Chinese and other foreign made
components without even inspecting them for Trojan horse viruses. These
technology transfers reflect the greed or naiveté of business leaders and the
incompetence and/or corruption on the part of government officials; Chinese
money had illegally gone to the campaigns of politicians from both parties. A
select committee chaired by Congressman Christopher Cox, he of SEC subprime
fame, reported that China
has more than 3,000 companies in the U.S. many of which are fronts for
acquiring advanced military technology; the full report remains classified.[152]
Yet another technological danger occurs with the global integration of computer
networks where lax security may give hostile powers the potential to bring down
major economic or defense systems.[153]
Far from expressing concern about outsourcing the
Department of Defense in fact encourages it. A single source of supply is no
reason to exclude foreign sourcing provided the producing country has political
stability. Even physical distance from the U.S. is not regarded as a
sufficient risk meriting exclusion. Thus China can be a major supplier of
weapons components. This assumes of course that foreign countries can be
trusted with defense secrets and will always be responsible suppliers. The DOD claims that it can’t supply Congress
with a list of components and countries of origin; but this may really be a
result of the feared public backlash that might result if such were made known.[154]
U.S.
trade policy has clearly resulted in increasing American vulnerability in time
of war and international crises. By 2007 America had lost its dominance in
the following security essential high tech manufactures: optical-electronics,
information and communications systems, advanced materials, life sciences and
flexible manufacturing; $369 billion of such products were imported in that
year. And a primary source of these
products is China
and other East Asian nations subject to Chinese pressure.[155]
This irresponsible drive to outsource vital defense
products shows no sign of slowing down. Recently the Obama administration awarded
a $1 billion contract to Brazilian aircraft manufacturer Embraer, a company
under investigation by the SEC for corrupt practices. This was done at the
expense of American company Hawker Beechcraft. Hawker management accuses the
DOD of favoritism to Embraer from the very beginning of the procurement
process. In addition to the loss of
American jobs and the effect of such outsourcing on national security, it has
been reported that Embraer builds military aircraft for Iran .[156]
Another recent case illustrates how the export of high
tech expertise to China
benefits U.S.
adversaries. Chinese telecommunications company ZTE sold Iran a cutting edge surveillance
and monitoring system which, among other uses, will enable the Iranian
government to crack down on dissidents. Iran
has found a way to evade the American ban on non-humanitarian sales by
purchasing from China .
ZTE has utilized in its devices hardware and software products from the
following American companies: Microsoft, Hewlett-Packard, Oracle, Cisco
Systems, Dell, Juniper Networks and Symantec.[157]
In late 2011 the US Senate Armed Services Committee
reported 1,800 cases in which the Pentagon had been sold counterfeit
electronics components. The committee estimates that a total of more than a
million fake parts had made their way into U.S. warplanes. Most of the fake
parts originated in China ,
some came from resale points in the United
Kingdom and Canada . Chinese commentator Song
Xiaojun pins the blame on American trade and defense policy. "The US has been dismantling its factories since the
1960s … And since the Clinton government, the US has
turned a blind eye towards military requisitioning. As it keeps cutting its
procurement budget, weapons dealers will keep providing cheaper quality
products."[158]
Even without supplying strategic high technology
expertise and outsourcing defense procurement to dubious foreign trading partners,
the mere fact of high trade deficits, budget deficits and national debt has
serious implications for U.S security. We have turned to borrowing on a massive
scale with foreigners owning a large part of Treasury and corporate securities
as well as a good chunk of corporate assets. Moreover resulting from the
massive debtor-creditor relationship between the U.S. and China is the
following paradox: “as China and the United States entwine their economies,
their military forces are devoting enormous planning and resources to possible
conflict, much as Germany and Britain became increasingly economically
integrated before World War I even as each tried to build a larger navy than
the other’s.”[159]
Impact on Health and Safety
There is yet another externality that must be subtracted
from the vaunted benefits of free trade. As we have seen American workers have
been forced to compete against those in China and other nations where
extremely lax environmental, labor, safety and other regulations are the rule.
In addition to the hollowing out of American manufacturing with a massive loss
of jobs, American consumers are subjected to a host of hazardous imports. The
pharmaceuticals industry is one case in point. More than 80% of active
ingredients in American prescription drugs are imported with only 18% of the
manufacturers known. Many manufacturers have, therefore, never even been
inspected by the FDA; China
and India
are home to most medicinal counterfeiters.[160]
In his aptly named book, Dangerous Business, Pat Choate
tabulates a few of the major health and safety instances due to substandard,
hazardous or toxic imports.[161
·
Air Transport: The FAA reported that counterfeit
parts played a role in 174 aircraft accidents between 1973 and 1996.
·
Pharmaceuticals: 25% of medicines from Mexico
are counterfeit, substandard, contaminated or poisoned. Canadian imports of
pharmaceuticals from nations associated with counterfeiting have surged; these
may not be sold in Canada
since these nations (China ,
Argentina etc.) have a good manufacturing practices agreement with Canada but they can be transshipped to the U.S.
·
Pet foods:
Competitive pressures force pet food manufacturers to use the cheapest
components and these come from China .
Wheat gluten in pet foods purchased from a Chinese company charging 20 cents a
pound less than its U.S.
competitors resulted in melamine-contaminated pet foods.
·
Sweeteners: In May 2007 the New York Times
reported that thousands of people have died worldwide due to the sale by a
Chinese manufacturer of diethylene glycol as a sweetener.
·
Food imports: In one month, April 2007, FDA
inspectors seized 107 shipments of tainted food imports, more than 1000
shipments of dietary supplements, toxic cosmetics and tainted medicines.
·
Rejected shipments: Between mid-2006 and
mid-2007 the FDA rejected 1,901 shipments from China ,
1,782 from India , 1,560 from
Mexico , 862 from the Dominican Republic and 82 from Denmark .
·
Poultry: In 2006 the poultry industry got the
DOA to approve the processing of chickens in China
that were raised in North America . So American
consumers can end up “buying chicken raised and killed in Mexico , frozen and put into containers, shipped
across the Pacific Ocean, processed in China ,
put back into containers, and then sent back across the ocean for distribution
and sale in the United
States .”
“In sum, the United States ’ approach to
globalization has been to openly accept goods of all kinds from anywhere,
including those for human consumption, even as the government’s capacity to
inspect those products for their safety is reduced.”[162]
International Trade: Historical Perspective
We have already seen the effects of the loss of
manufacturing and trade supremacy in the case of Britain ,
Spain and Italy . Nations that cease to make
things and live off of their accumulated wealth or reputations are on the road
to ruin. The history of trade also shows that clever protectionist policies can
yield great economic benefits. There are two general lessons that might be
drawn from the study of trade history. One is that the lowering of trade
barriers usually follows rather than precedes economic development. In addition the most successful pursuers of
free trade have tended to be small maritime states such as Hong Kong and Singapore ; or historically the city states of
the ancient world as well as medieval Italy and the Baltic. Here their
comparative advantage consisted of their favorable locations which were well
suited to the role of trading and transshipment centers.[163]
Ancient World and Southern Europe
The most famous of the ancient world’s maritime cities
was Athens which became the dominant trading
nation in the Mediterranean . She was largely
free of tariffs but did establish a trading monopoly in the Black Sea and in
the Aegean . With its monopoly position on these
waterways and it’s almost monopoly position in the rest of the eastern
Mediterranean, Athens
was hardly a paragon of free trade. In fact when she lost that position with
the Macedonian and then the Roman conquest, Athens entered a permanent economic decline.
These later rulers shifted industry and trade away from Athens
to more favored cities; Alexandria , Antioch , Rhodes .
Ancient China
was also no paragon of free trade and was able to maintain its economic
vitality by protecting its vital trade secrets. In the 2nd century BC the
Chinese opened the countries of Central Asia for Chinese trade via the famous Silk Road . The silk trade was ultimately extended to the
neighboring countries of Korea
and Japan , and then to India and Persia . Silk was also sent by ships
and caravans across mountains and deserts into Europe .
The Chinese kept their economic advantage by keeping the secret of silk
production for centuries. Those who attempted to compromise the secret or to
smuggle butterflies, caterpillars or eggs out of China were subject to the death
penalty.
We have seen how 16th century Spain by
relying on foreign sources for its manufacturing needs fell into a long economic
decline. When the great influx of bullion slowed down in the 17th
century the Spanish lost their ability to innovate and manufacture; in the
meantime its European rivals learned good work habits, and new ways of
production. The Spanish monarchy became mired deeply in debt which was followed
by a sequence of bankruptcies.
In addition to the enervating effects of Spain ’s sudden wealth
in bullion, the powerful landholders triumphed over the nascent manufacturing
sector. Agricultural and livestock interests gained economic dominance;
agricultural interests were nurtured and protected while manufacturers were
unshielded against foreign imports. The resulting deindustrialization has
plagued the Spanish economy ever since. This circumstance stands in marked
contrast to that of the European nations to the north, and eventually to the United States ,
where aristocratic agricultural or plantation interests were subdued by the
rising power of protected industry and by the urban bourgeoisie. The once great
mercantile nation, Portugal ,
followed closely in the footsteps of its neighbor with agricultural and mining
interests winning out over unprotected manufacturers. The Italian city states
also followed Iberia
into an economic decline resulting from a failure to protect its manufacturing
and to innovate. Foreign trade eventually acted as an engine of decline causing
a shift of resources away from Italy ’s
once vaunted manufactured products into agriculture.
British economic history is a classic example of a
nation’s rise to industrial dominance under a policy of protectionism followed
by an unraveling when such policies are abandoned. England ’s medieval international
trade was dominated by wool production and manufactures. English rulers adopted
an early form of Industrial policy. By
curtailing wool exports English monarchs encouraged Flemish cloth manufacturers
to migrate to England ;
protectionism grew hand in hand with the royal power. Flemish producers were
protected by economies of scale produced by enormous capital investments. Only
government action could get English producers entry into the industry.
The rise of England as an economic superpower
in cloth manufacturing and in other industries can be traced to a long series
of industrial policy regulations. Henry I prohibited the importation of Spanish
wool. Early on the English authorities made effective use of customs duties. In
the late 13th century Parliament authorized a tax on wool shipped
from English ports. This was at first a token amount but later on was upped to
25% of the value of the crop and was eventually extended to all commodities
exported from English ports. These duties became a major source of revenue for
the Crown. This prohibition of the export of much coveted English wool gave
domestic manufacturers a competitive supply advantage. This was accompanied by
government encouragement of the cloth dying and finishing industry. Land tenure
arrangements were also modified to enable large scale sheep-raising. Fishing
was still another industry receiving official encouragement.
Edward III was the ruler who first lured Flemish weavers to
bring their technical expertise to England and also prohibited the
wearing of foreign manufactured cloth. Edward VI ended the trading privileges
of the Hanseatic cities and English domination of the textile industry was used
as a wedge to drive the Hanseatic League out
of the market for other products. In 1489 Henry VII imposed a tariff on woolen
goods. Elizabeth
I also gave military support enabling English mariners to break into the Baltic
trade.
Therefore, in Britain industrial promotion took
the forms of defense against outside competition and protection of supplies of
raw materials for domestic producers. The later navigation acts extended these
protections to British shippers. The later mid-nineteenth century to 1930 record
of British free trade obscures the earlier commitment to economic nationalism. Britain was the
dominant economic power prior to its experiment with free trade. At the beginning of the 19th
century, Britain
had a tariff on manufactures averaging some 50 percent higher than that of any
of its competitors. At about that time Britain ’s leaders reversed policy
in the sure expectation that free trade would result in their domination of the
new global industrial economy with the rest of the world serving as a source of
agricultural products and raw materials. For a brief time in mid century the
strategy appeared to work; but then some of Britain’s foreign competitors
withdrew from that game by embracing forms of protectionism and industrial
policy.
Of course some producers feeling the heat of foreign
competition called for a return to protectionism. They pointed out that while Britain
opened its doors to everyone other nations erected tariffs and other trade
barriers. Other nations subsidized their industries, dumped their goods at less
than home market prices and engaged in other unfair business practices. As a
result one British industry after another wilted and contracted before the
outpouring of cheap foreign goods.
However free trade had become a matter of faith for the
British establishment and despite increasingly obvious failure they persisted
in the great gamble of free trade abroad and no domestic industrial policy. In
addition certain domestic economic interests had become addicted to the profits
they were obtaining from free trade even while manufacturing declined. And the
dubious economic logic behind free trade was accompanied by the Victorian
missionary moral zeal of bringing British economic ideals along with British
civilization to the benighted masses of both Europe
and the rest of the world. Petty concerns regarding the loss of industrial
leadership were regarded as virtually sacrilegious. This 19th
century British policy mistake is one they are now repeating with open borders
and mass immigration.
The chemical industry is one striking example of Britain ’s
loss of its manufacturing supremacy. In 1857 William Perkin discovered and set
up a plant for making aniline blue dye. However, this early lead in chemistry
was lost to the rising industrial power of Germany . Britain ’s failure to protect its industry
and to commit itself to the training of chemists and technicians resulted in
the loss of its comparative advantage in chemical production. By World War I ,
Germany had established
itself as the world leader; so far behind were Britain and the rest of the world
that they could not even benefit from the wartime confiscation of German
chemical patents. It was only following World War I that America , using
some clever Industrial espionage was able to close the gap.
While the western German states preserved policies
promoting freedom of trade and enterprise, an idea introduced in Napoleonic
times, other states returned to more regimented policies. Prussia and most medium sized
states chose a middle course, liberalizing trade while keeping some
restrictions. By the 1840s there was a
definite shift to protective tariffs and a new pan-German customs system. The
new system took a middle course between the British and Swiss free-trade system
and the more protective policies pursued by Russia ,
Austria , France and the U.S. In many parts of Germany
protective industrial associations were formed; these were a source of
commercial and financial advice to the various states. A close relationship
grew up between the governments and these associations. Eventually government
became the decisive force in pursuing those economic affairs of particular national
interest.
Following Bismarck ’s
unification of Germany ,
bankers, industrialists, academics and the military cooperated to make Germany the most advanced industrial power in Europe . The state built the communications and
transportation infrastructure, subsidized technical education and scientific research,
provided social security for its workers, established a discriminatory patent
system and adopted mercantilist trade policies raising tariffs and subsidizing
exporters. Furthermore, German government, banks and corporations working
systematically and together monopolized global markets for dozens of technology
based products. The banks were intimately involved in industry where they would
own stock and have seats on boards. They also operated foreign branches and
helped open markets for German goods. They helped collect foreign economic and
political intelligence and became knowledgeable on the workings of foreign
competitors. They facilitated cartels and curtailed domestic competition
thereby lowering costs, raising prices and eliminating risks; all of which
helped them break into foreign markets.
German industry had to dominate foreign markets to gain
the scale of operations it needed. The German government actively assisted its
companies in stealing foreign technology. German industry also advanced by
destroying its foreign competition through kickbacks, bribery, predatory
litigation, industrial theft, price cutting, underhand rebates and sabotage. In
Germany , in contrast to America , these
predatory and monopolistic activities were actively abetted by government. For
instance IG Farben used a strategy of dumping by lowering prices until U.S.
or foreign competitors were driven out of business. German patent strategy
aimed to protect their technological secrets by erecting corporate and
government barriers to industrial espionage, using only Germans in key
industrial positions and avoiding building factories abroad. In the U.S. they made a practice of hiring
the best politically connected lawyers to file patent applications and prevent
patent infringement. German companies also manipulated their patent
descriptions omitting vital details, inserting false information and concealing
key ingredients; all this designed to misdirect competitors in their research
and to evade foreign patent regulations.
The German chemical industry pioneered these methods
assisted by the indifference of the mid-nineteenth century British government.
British chemist William Perkins was the first to discover the new chemical
dyes. He mistakenly believed that
British and European patents protected him from intellectual property theft.
But he did not count on the lack of protection by his own government when in
1858 on purely technical grounds the French government denied him a patent. The
German government immediately saw an opportunity for the acquisition by their
own industry of an indispensable product with many potential uses. The German
chemical industry quickly rose to global domination; by 1900 six large German
companies controlled the synthetic dye industry. The Germans were not better at
chemistry than the British; it was simply that they valued science and
technology more. The British spent relatively little on science and technical
education and their universities never built the scientific and technical
linkages with industry as the Germans had done.
The Americans were also victimized by German predatory
practices in the chemical industry but they eventually learned to fight back
effectively. In 1917 DuPont examined German chemical patents finding booby
traps that could produce explosions if these formulas were replicated.
Congressional hearings after the war revealed that dependence on German imports
was a result of the German government, banks and corporations working together
to monopolize markets for technology based goods. In 1919 Congress erected a
high tariff wall against the import of organic chemical products and chartered
the Chemical Foundation to administer the German chemical patents that were
seized in 1917. Herbert Dow, founder of Dow Chemical, was a leader in the U.S. chemical
counterattack. As a result of his experience with the German chemical cartel he
came to the belief that the U.S.
should not be dependent on another nation for the supply of vital chemical
goods. Soon afterward Dow Chemical established itself as the leader in
magnesium production facilities. This enabled it to share its technology with
other U.S. firms to supply the
magnesium for the planes and weapons needed by the U.S.
following Pearl Harbor .
The economic history of 19th century France
is an example of a badly thought out policy of protectionism. In the second
half of the 19th century: French entrepreneurs prized security above all else
and this meant protection from foreign competition. For most of this period
French industry was protected by a series of duties and prohibitions. This
created an over dependence by French entrepreneurs on high tariffs and other
protective government policies. This attitude goes back to the days of the old
regime where, unlike in Britain ,
the French manufacturer was more a government functionary than an independent
entrepreneur. French industry was nurtured by the central administration. In
the Napoleonic period this fundamentally infantile dependency was strengthened.
All of this is in contrast to the daring shown by early 19th century
American and British entrepreneurs.
The prevalent attitude turned into one not of protecting
innovative infant industries but rather one of preserving obsolete and
inefficient production. The protections
given to French iron producers were undermined by high duties on coal and coke,
despite the obvious dependence of France on external supplies of this
fuel. Other drags on French economic growth were the high levels of taxation,
high military expenditures and the vast army of government employees. Labor was
thus denied to productive operations and devoted instead to bureaucratic
interference with industry. Another misguided policy was the requirement that a
license be purchased for goods shipped abroad raising the prices of French
goods and creating a disincentive for foreign purchasers. The French experience
illustrates the failure to use protection sparingly and intelligently. It shows
that protectionism is not a sufficient policy; there were very different results
in France and America
despite both nations having protectionist policies. Indeed, one must be
cautious that protectionism is not overly relied upon since, wrongly applied,
it may end up deadening a nation’s competitive and innovative spirit.
Modern Asia
The distinctive German pioneered strategy of government
sponsored and subsidized economic development was taken up in the 20th
century by Japan , China and Korea . Japan was the first Asian country
to adopt the German cartel model along with its manipulation of foreign
competitors, governments and politicians. Early in the century when Japan was developing its modern economy large
foreign demand for its silk allowed Japan to import manufactured goods
at prices too cheap for Japanese producers to match. Japanese authorities
quickly set about countering this feedback from its strong currency by
instituting tariffs. And as was the case in America , the rural economies bore
the cost of this development.
After World War 2 the Japanese rejected suggestions that
they once again become a nation of fishermen and villages. Instead they
followed the example of Alexander Hamilton and Henry VII by closing their
markets to the goods of selected industries that they targeted for entry while
welcoming the import of the foreign technology that they lacked. Japan ’s basic
strategy was to break into a target industry, wipe out its competitors and then
successively hand the industry down to less sophisticated neighbors while
focusing on the next up and coming technology. So over the second half of the
20th century they shifted their moving target from garments to cheap
fabricated goods to higher end consumer electronics and then to robotics. And Japan became the template for all of East Asia: Korea , China ,
Taiwan , Vietnam , Hong Kong and Singapore .
An examination of American economic history reveals that
laissez-faire trade policies were seldom the rule until very recently. Britain ’s
American colonies were established and governed for the benefit of British
mercantile interests. Protecting Britain ’s economic interests
sometimes entailed providing benefits to colonial merchants and planters. The British
sugar trade in the 17th century was a great profit center for local
planters as well as for British merchants. The West Indies
were the perfect colony; they supplied tropical commodities and imported
English services and manufactures. The
profits of such tightly controlled trade helped finance the British industrial
revolution. The Navigation Acts of the 17th and 18th
centuries restricted shipping from the colonies to English owned vessels. These
included ship owners in the colonies which made the carry trade a very
profitable one for American businessmen and helped set the stage for the
American shipbuilding industry.
However, as the North American colonies grew economically
British policies were seen to be constrictive. The American Revolution was a
war in which the commercial elite of the Colonies revolted against their
inferior role in Britain ’s
Atlantic economy. After the Revolution merchant and industrial interests
attempted to put an end to America ’s
inferior role; by 1788 nine out of thirteen states, mostly in the North had
tariff legislation. Even such advocates of free trade as Franklin, Madison,
Jefferson, and John Adams had become convinced that the survival of American
manufacturing required at least temporary protection from the flood of imports.
In those early days the balance of trade was consistently running against America due to imports of raw materials and
manufactured goods of which Britain
was the chief supplier. Imports were also brought in from other European
nations and even China
was able to send its tea directly to American ports after independence. The
American carry trade did help to ameliorate the situation somewhat; many
imports were brought in on American ships.
With the adoption
of the constitution, the new national government moved immediately to protect
American industry; the tariff of 1789 was the very second bill signed by
President Washington. This act signed into law on July 4 had a number of
objectives. Financing the Federal government was primary but it was also
enacted for the encouragement and protection of American manufactures. The Tonnage
Act was passed in the same month to insure that the thriving carry trade industry
was protected by charging higher fees on foreign ships in U.S. ports and reserving the
fishing business and coastal trade for Americans.
Alexander Hamilton was the most zealous and articulate
advocate of American manufacturing with his Report on Manufactures of 1793.
However, opposition from Southern planters delayed the adoption of his reforms
until the War of 1812 finally solidified support for protectionism. Another early proponent of protecting U.S. manufacturing
was Treasury Secretary Gallatin. He pushed through the replacement of various
unpopular internal taxes with a two and one half percent increase in the levy
on taxable imports. Uncannily resonant with our own times this was named the
Mediterranean Fund and was designed as a temporary tax for financing the war
against the Barbary pirates.
During the entire period from 1789 to 1816 revenue was
still the chief motive of U.S.
tariff policies. Duties averaged 10% but were doubled during the War of 1812. That
war marked the final conversion of American free traders like Jefferson and
Madison into economic realists who realized that if the U.S. lacked the
means of producing weapons and essential goods it would always remain a
vulnerable nation. The resulting American System with high protective tariffs
enabled the nation to eventually evolve into the world’s mightiest industrial
power. The first milestone of the new system was the 1816 Tariff Act with
protection as the dominant motive. The success of these early tariff policies,
along with such others as funding the debt stimulated commerce and industry; these
demonstrate that a moderate protectionist tariff combined with other
intelligent economic policies can work very well.
However, the U.S. over the following four
decades became a bit too addicted to high tariffs. This resulted in a cyclical
policy of excessively high tariffs followed by over-correcting toward the low
side. In 1816 industrial interests
pushed up the average tariff from 25 to 35 percent; in 1820 it was pushed up to
40%. In the 1828 Tariff of Abominations duties reached 50%; but were
subsequently reduced. In the 1840s in
imitation of British liberalism there was an episode of free trade. But after a series of recessions
protectionism made a major comeback just prior to the Civil War.
Throughout these pre-Civil War years of cyclical tariffs,
Americans did not fall into the trap of hindering the free flow of capital. The
developing U.S.
economy benefitted greatly from foreign investment. England was the best market for
American securities before and then after the War of 1812. Barings of London
were leaders in the placement of American securities along with their American
counterpart, the Bayards of New York. These were active in land and security
speculation and served as financial advisers to European investors. The Bank of
the United States
along with Astor and Sons and Brown Brothers functioned as investment bankers
for the placement of American securities.
Economic historians are divided in their evaluation of
ante-bellum tariff policy. Some like Jane Jacobs emphasize the positive
beneficial feedback effects of tariffs on stimulated import-replacing
activities on Northern cities. Unfortunately this did not work for the backward
cities of the South which would have needed their own protection from Northern
manufactures. Indeed some economists and historians point to the intimate
connection between slavery and free trade. Because slaves are unsuitable for
industrial work all slave societies from the ancient world to modern times have
failed to industrialize; they are saddled with their comparative advantage in a
slave based agricultural economy. Other economists with a free trade
orientation maintain that such policies continued longer than necessary and
served to transfer income from consumers to producers. However, many of them
grudgingly concede that protection may have facilitated economies of scale, an
increase in the overall rate of capital formation, and the employment of
advanced manufacturing technologies.
The first three post Civil War decades were a period of
high tariffs and rapid industrial growth. The U.S. economy outpaced the rest of
the world despite continuing high tariffs. During the Civil War three minor
tariff acts had been passed in 1861 followed by a major tariff of July 1862. Some
of these tariffs were for the purpose of revenue; others were for infant
industry protection. However, afterward import duties were never again the most
important source of federal revenue and their protective function was dominant.
In 1864, the Morrill tariff was passed and remained in effect for 20 years
despite much opposition. With the latter the U.S. entered a period of high
tariffs coinciding with the long Republican hegemony from 1865 to 1932. During
that period, in marked contrast to recent years, the speeches of Republican
politicians were filled with concern for the American worker.
Republicans at that time believed that American
capitalism depended upon class harmony and that tariffs were a way of
reconciling the interests of labor and capital. However, as is the case today,
many members of the left and right intellectual elites found common ground in
opposing tariffs. The Social Darwinist William Graham Sumner who saw
protectionism as interfering with the free market and, therefore with the
survival of the fittest was on the same side as Karl Marx who thought that free trade was a useful means of undermining
capitalism.
In 1872 Congress modified the tariff reducing levies on a
wide range of imports and instead targeted the protection of manufacturing. Untaxed
imports surged from only five to nearly fifty percent with coffee and tea becoming
duty-free. By 1876 there was a general consensus for the necessity of tariff
protection as an employment measure on the part of both political parties.
However, rising protests over high tariffs led to the appointment of a Tariff
Commission in 1882; the commission was still dominated by representatives of
protected industries. The resulting tariff act of 1883 made some strictly
symbolic reductions while basically maintaining the old system of
protectionism. Even the Democrats under Cleveland
while favoring reduced tariffs, endorsed the position that allowance must be
made to account for the difference in wages between American and foreign
workers. After Cleveland
lost the 1888 election President Harrison helped usher in the McKinley tariff
which kept certain agricultural commodities such as raw sugar on the free list but
moved most tariffs in an upward direction.
It is noteworthy that this high tariff did not result in depression, as
Smoot-Hawley was later alleged to have done. The law also provided for
reciprocity treaties with foreign nations; a number were implemented with
western hemisphere nations. Despite these reciprocity provisions, the McKinley tariff
was the most protective tariff enacted up to that time.
The Wilson-Gorman Act of 1894 slightly reduced most of
these high rates but reinstituted the duty on sugar. The act also repealed the
reciprocity provisions. The strongly resented Dingley tariff of 1897 imposed a
52% average on dutiable imports. The Payne-Aldrich Act of 1909 moderated the
Dingley tariff; the average rate was cut to 42%. In 1913 Congress passed the
Underwood-Simmons Act which greatly expanded the list of exemptions while
keeping some moderate protections for domestic industry; the average tariff
rate fell to 36%. This tariff while passed by a supposedly free-trade Democrat
Congress was far from ideal free-trade. It primarily lowered rates on various
agricultural products and natural resources as well as selected manufactured
products. The continued protection contained in the Underwood Tariff was the
political price the new administration had to pay in return for passage of an
income tax.
In sum the post Civil War policy was a continuation of
American protectionism. Until the passage of an income tax, tariff revenues
were the only sources of federal funding once the short-lived income tax of the
Civil War ended. However, protection for American industry became the chief
object of tariff policy. Some economic historians deny that the protective
tariff, being a redistribution of income from consumers to producers, had much
effect on the nation’s economic growth. Countering that view is a comparison of
the massive expansion of the U.S.
and German economies with the decline and stagnation experienced by free trade Britain between
the Civil War and World War One. The adverse effects of high tariffs were
offset by increased capital formation and economies of scale in some protected
industries. In addition tariffs provided a large part of income for the Federal
government. In their absence there would have been reduced budget surpluses,
increased deficits and less federal debt retirement leading to less capital
formation and less growth. The 19th century experience is important
evidence that, although some tariffs were too high, tariff protection on the
whole was an important factor enabling U.S. economic growth. On the whole
tariffs did more good than harm.
The early 20th century was marked by a back
and forth struggle between the proponents and opponents of protectionism with
the protectionists gradually losing ground.
Following in the mistaken footprints of 19th century Britain the
American leadership developed an unwarranted confidence in the nation’s
invincible economic strength. The last stand of protectionism took place with
the passage of the Smoot Hawley tariff which was long blamed for the
intensification of the Depression. However, as Milton Friedman proved, the
major precipitating events of that calamity had their origin in the
ill-considered monetary policies of the Federal Reserve and occurred before the
tariff was passed. The Fed first allowed a bubble to arise and then overreacted
in constricting liquidity. This sequence is now generally accepted by
economists, even by Keynesian economists, and is a prime motivator behind current
Fed monetary policy.
Moreover, the law did not precipitate any severe foreign
retaliation along with trade wars causing the Depression to spread worldwide.
It impacted only about a third of America ’s trade, some one percent
of GDP. Nevertheless committed free trader Secretary of State Cordell Hull,
with little basis other than his belief that free trade promoted world peace,
persuaded Congress that Smoot-Hawley caused the Depression. Congress then
proceeded to delegate its authority over trade to the executive branch and America ’s
tariffs first started to come down for good in 1934. Ever since then free
traders have endeavored to keep tariffs out of the hands of Congress. By 1937
the U.S. had reciprocally cut tariffs with a number of Latin American and
European nations.
Following World War Two the U.S.
assumed declining Britain ’s
role as the chief promoter of free trade. In 1947 the General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade was established at U.S. prompting. Over the next forty
years tariffs were cut by some 35 percent. Once again foreign policy
considerations were paramount and this was a deliberate Cold War strategy aimed
at strengthening the economies of American allies. America , with its belief in its
economic invincibility, became the only major market open to trade. U.S. trade policy was accompanied by the
Marshall Plan which supplied Europe with the
capital needed to rebuild. U.S.
aid and capital also provided Europe as well as Japan
with the wherewithal to buy U.S.
imports and to reindustrialize; they were not yet serious economic competitors.
With détente and the dwindling of the economic threat
from the Soviet Union in the 1960s it would have been a good time for America to slow
and reverse its plunge into free trade. But in their arrogant belief in
permanent American supremacy U.S.
policymakers made the exact same mistake the British had made a century before.
Free trade was boosted by the Trade Expansion Act of 1962
giving the president wide authority to reduce existing tariffs and ease other
restrictions. This initiated the Kennedy round of trade agreements which
extended through 1967; the average tariff fell some five percentage points from
1967 to 1972. However, U.S.
policymakers did not consider that America ’s trading partners were
gearing up and that the Bretton Woods system was beginning to collapse. By an
unfortunate confluence this was just about the same time that the 1965 Immigration
Act and the Great Society came into effect; the 60s ideologies now began working together
to undermine America’s economic vitality. It was in the 1960s with expenditures
for the Great Society and Vietnam War that the U.S. first began running trade
deficits and the dollar began its decline.
Interestingly it was Kennedy’s liberal economics guru
J.K. Galbraith who was one of those to warn about the adverse effects of
further trade liberalization in 1964. And it was in the late 1960s with the
Japanese take-over of the black and white TV, camera, transistor radio and toy
industries that the first serious trade-related cracks in the economy became
visible. There was a trade deficit in 1971 which ultimately became permanent.
In August 1971 to stop the bleeding Nixon closed the gold window and currencies
began to float. Nixon also imposed a temporary surcharge on the tariff.
There were other voices joining that of Galbraith against
free trade at that time. The Senate passed protectionist legislation in 1968
only to have it killed in the House. Labor reversed its earlier support for the
Kennedy round and turned against free trade. Nixon’s Commerce Secretary
considered creating an industrial policy coordinating agency which was killed
through lack of Congressional support. In 1972 the AFL-CIO supported a bill
which would have imposed quotas on some imports in addition to imposing
restrictions on capital exports.
President Carter resisted such protectionism while preferring
to continue the Cold War tool of free trade. President Reagan also vetoed two
protectionist bills in 1985 and 1988 and his successor Bush vetoed one in 1990.
When the dollar rose as a result of the policies of Volcker and Reagan,
America’s trade balances were rising and there was a perpetual deficit; a process that flooded other countries with dollars giving them a
great incentive to embrace globalization. The dismantling of capital controls
resulting from globalization resulted in assets held outside of home countries
to increase from some $3 trillion in 1980 to almost $50 trillion 25 years
later.
It is true that Reagan was more of a trade pragmatist
than his predecessors or his successors. He achieved a voluntary auto import
restriction agreement with Japan
and he protected other endangered industries such as motorcycles, steel, lumber
and computer chips. However, his trade pragmatism, while preferable to the trade
extremism of his successors was not based on any underlying theoretical critique
of free trade and all of his interventions were rather ad hoc. A last major
attempt at creating an industrial policy was that of Commerce Secretary
Baldridge who wanted to turn the Commerce Department into the equivalent of Japan ’s
Ministry of International Trade and Industry. The free market ideologues in the
Reagan administration and the office of the U.S. Trade Representative dispensed
with that idea.
Protectionism in isolation is insufficient and may even
be self-defeating. It is incumbent for a nation to actively seek sources of
future comparative advantage. Nurturing and protecting invention and discovery
are the best means to that end. The encouragement of invention through patent
protection was a longtime English tradition.
In the mid 15th century the English crown granted a 20 year
monopoly to a Flemish glassmaker for a method of producing window glass in
return for instructing English glassmakers in his technique.
The leadership of the early American nation was
well-schooled in the benefits provided by the English patent system. In April
1790 Washington
made patent protection a priority and signed the Patent Act followed shortly by
the Copyright Act. President Washington and Congress then turned to Alexander Hamilton
to develop a strategy to reduce U.S.
dependence on foreign imports. In
December 1791 Hamilton
submitted his Report on Manufactures.
The report had implicit within it the infant industry argument along
with proposals to build an American industrial base. Hamilton proposed a strong patent system in
addition to a high tariff wall. Moreover, Hamilton and the Congress were
determined to see America
industrialize by whatever means necessary; industrial espionage was not deemed
out of bounds. They were joined in this determination by American merchants and
manufacturers. The first American success in obtaining crucial foreign
technology preceded the Patent Act and Hamilton’s report. The British protected their technology by
forbidding exports of their new textile machines and making the emigration of
those possessing this knowledge illegal. Despite this in 1789 Samuel Slater
managed to migrate to Rhode Island
and set up operations using the Arkwright spinning machine.
Twenty years later Francis Cabot Lowell plotted to steal
the plans for the Cartwright loom.
He went to England in 1810 and managed to
learn and bring back the secrets of this English power-driven device. Lowell
and his colleagues then determined on a means of protecting American textiles
manufactured with this pirated British technology. They induced Daniel Webster
and John Calhoun to push through a protective tariff of 30% on cotton and
woolen imports. By acquiring this new means of mass production Lowell
brought the industrial revolution to America . The Tariff of 1816 protected
American manufacturers from being undersold through the deliberate policies of their
British competitors.
Some free-trade favoring economic historians maintain that
the American textile industry was strong enough by the 1820s to compete without
this additional tariff protection. However such a free trade policy could only
have succeeded provided it was accompanied by subsidies to a few pilot plants
trying out and perfecting the new manufacturing techniques. The precedent for that already existed in the
government subsidies for gun making. At a later date it was followed by
government assistance for the new telegraph technology; the subsidized pilot
projects developed the technology which was later adopted by others. In pig
iron production a lowering of protection after 1846 was extremely detrimental
to older producers; those with newer technology fared better. The conclusion
these historians arrive at is that while tariffs were not critical in the
growth of infant industries they did stimulate greater savings and capital
formation in the protected industries. These considerations show that tariffs
and industrial policy are best used in an interrelated manner. Industrial policy
along with reasonable protective tariffs appears to be beneficial in the very
early stages of a new industry enabling the capital formation needed for scale
economies in manufacturing. Government assistance and subsidies are the way
that Japan
and other Asian countries have developed even without erecting openly defiant
tariff barriers.
The Patent Act of 1836 extended inventor protections and
established a federal bureaucracy for evaluation and administration of new
patents. Congress voted a subsidy for the first experimental telegraph line in
1843. By 1861 the coasts were connected.
Now Californians had the same information at the same time as those in New York with obvious
implications for the integration of the financial markets. During the Civil War
Lincoln became a major promoter of U.S. industry. His industrial
policy included the encouragement and support of advancements in telegraphy,
railroads, agriculture, arms and steel. In addition the U.S. government
authorized the transcontinental railroad, passed the Land Grant College Act and
built the first steel battleships; an innovation that was ultimately adopted by
the private sector. Under Lincoln
the term of patent protection was extended from 14 to 17 years. As a result of
this expanded patent protection the number of patent applications increased
from 12,000 annually in the 1860s to 25,000 in the 1880s and 40,000 in 1914.
In addition to
patents, copyright protection was also an ongoing American initiative. The 1790
Copyright Act both prohibited piracy of works by U.S. citizens and encouraged the
theft of foreign materials. Henry Clay was a great advocate of international
copyright protection and of the benefits of agreements with foreign nations;
ultimately the U.S.
changed its policy and ceased to encourage the sort of piracy that infuriated
foreign authors such as Dickens. The importance of copyright protection to
technological innovation has become apparent in recent years. The Semiconductor
Protection Act of 1984 permitted the copyrighting of the three dimensional
masks used to create new computer chips. In 1998 the Digital Millennium
Copyright Act provided for the ratification of a global copyright treaty.
The U.S.
greatly benefited from the creation of new sources of comparative advantage
through intellectual property protection, infrastructure development and well
thought out industrial policy. America
was blessed by plentiful natural resources and a large domestic market. But
given these, it was still necessary for its amazing economic success that the
market be protected by a high trade wall. Additional factors were low
population densities with limited skilled labor which created a demand for
mechanization; a lesson that appears lost on the present day proponents of
cheap immigrant labor. There was also the strong imperative toward widespread
literacy and a popular culture of invention and innovation. However, there was
one unfortunate consequence of early U.S. government economic strategy;
and one that points to the dangers that may accrue from unbalanced development.
The government sponsored promotion of technological change coupled with the
development of transportation facilities to implement the export industry was
of particular benefit to the northern cities. The trade pattern that developed
tied the South to the goods and services provided by the North. If the South had possessed an ambitious elite
with the goal to industrialize like that of the North or of modern Japan and China for that matter, the tragedy
of the Civil War might have been averted.
Policy Implications
Restoring America ’s
depleted industrial base and reducing its balance of trade deficit should
become a priority. Proposed fixes vary
from reforming tariff policy, obtaining more favorable trade agreements, moving
toward more favorable exchange rates, protecting intellectual property and well-crafted
industrial policies.
Tariffs
A tariff is a crude but often-used method of altering
trade flows; as we have seen the U.S. policy up until the mid 20th
century was one of tariff protection. The economic problem is to determine the
optimal tariff which maximizes national welfare while mitigating certain
unfortunate side effects. One of these is the distortion of both production and
consumption incentives. As seen above in the case of 19th century France
these can be quite detrimental. The other major shortcoming of tariffs is that foreign
retaliation may spiral into trade warfare. Appendix 2F contains a theoretical
example of trade warfare.
Fletcher proposes a natural strategic tariff that would
“have different effects on industries that were at different points on their
cost curves.” He recommends a flat tax
on all imported goods and services. Such a tax (about 30%) would not cause
low-tech industries like apparel to relocate back to the U.S. since the
difference in the wage rate is too high. However it would cause the relocation
back here of high tech manufacturing such as semiconductors; precisely the ones
we would want.[164]
One levy on imports that should certainly be considered
is a “human rights” tariff.[165]
This would take into account environmental standards and labor conditions in
exporting nations. As we have seen some nations, China
in particular, have working conditions that were abolished a century ago in the
United States .
China
is well known for its lack of pollution controls and environmental regulation.
All has been sacrificed to the goal of rapid industrial development. It is
grossly unfair to require American workers and business to compete in such
circumstances.
The question of currency devaluation and exchange rate
manipulation is closely tied to that of tariffs. The question is simply how
well tariffs would work under a regime of floating exchange rates. Examples
from the history of protectionism were from a time of the gold standard and
fixed exchange rates. Floating exchange rates and international capital
mobility with their corresponding sale of assets and debt can enable a
profligate nation to follow bad economic policies for very long periods of time
without consequences. Moreover it is relatively easy for countries like China to competitively devalue their currencies
as a counter to U.S.
protectionism. Fletcher counters this argument by noting that “we can end
foreign currency manipulation at any time simply by restricting or taxing
foreigners’ ability to lend us debt and buy our assets. We would need to raise
our own savings rate if we did this (or face rising interest rates), but we
need to do this anyway.”[166]
The U.S. ,
of course, can also use a competitive devaluation of the dollar to improve its
trade balance. The possibility of a trade war and global depression resulting
from tariff protectionism or competitive devaluations is an objection that is
frequently made to such policies. However, the view of many economists today,
as expressed by Samuelson is that “it is less clear that trade wars and
competitive devaluations were major causes of the Depression. More likely, they
were consequences … the futile defense of the gold standard was the primary
cause of the Depression.”[167]
There is a more relevant objection to a policy of dollar devaluation. Given the
self-inflicted dependence the U.S.
now has on foreign suppliers and the deterioration of the American skill base
in many industries there are no longer domestic alternatives and devaluation
will simply result in a steep rise in the prices of many goods. Above all, the
dependence on foreign oil is a killer argument against devaluation. Such
dependence has been exacerbated as compared to other developed nations by the
American pattern of low density suburban land use and decades of neglect for
mass transit.[168]
Industrial Targeting
Industrial policy through targeting particular industries
is another possible means of improving the balance of trade. Such targeting
should be highly focused; the big problem is not one of keeping low-tech
industries paying low wages but in the erosion of high-tech industries with
highly skilled workers. Porter characterizes the form such targeting should
take:
Policy must shift to much more indirect forms of
government assistance designed to support efforts by any industry to upgrade
its demand conditions, human resources, and scientific expertise. Government
also has a legitimate and important role in encouraging the development of
particular skills or technologies that are important to upgrading in a
substantial number of industries.[169]
Appendix 2G contains a theoretical argument for
industrial targeting; it can be beneficial under some but not all conditions.
East Asia provides the paradigm for a successful
industrial policy with Japan
being the pioneer in that endeavor. In the postwar period up until the early
1970s MITI supervised the allocation of resources to heavy industry such as
steel and away from traditional labor intensive industries like textiles. Thus,
current comparative advantage was sacrificed so that future comparative
advantage in superior industries could be created. It should be noted that the
great economic success experienced by Japan was, undoubtedly, helped
along by the quality of its population and by its culture of work and business.
After 1970 there was a shift to the emphasis of
developing knowledge-intensive high tech industries with semiconductors and
robotics becoming targets. The steel industry might well have developed in the
absence of government direction due to Japan ’s high savings rate and
falling transport costs. “Nonetheless, it is a good guess that the Japanese
government encouraged steel to grow even faster than it would have in a
free-market economy.”[170]
The joint semiconductor research projects and the tacit buy-Japanese policy,
which would have been forbidden in the U.S. by anti-trust laws, were
highly effective in enabling Japanese manufacturers to advance their skills in
high technology.[171]
Europeans have also had industrial targeting policies
with rather more mixed results than in the case of Japan . France , for example, has
concentrated on picking “national champions” able to compete internationally.
The government has ushered in a series of mergers to create large firms, has
implemented a number of monopolistic privileges and has provided subsidies to
aircraft in particular. While the French economy has performed well, its
industrial policy, unlike that of Japan , seems to have had higher
costs incurred than benefits obtained.
One result was the Concorde, a consortium of Britain
and France ,
which has been a financial failure but has helped to seed such future aircraft
production as Airbus. The latter, a consortium of European governments, has
been a success at producing commercially viable aircraft, but with higher costs
than its chief competition, Boeing, it requires subsidies. Nevertheless it does
illustrate the large economies of scale that can occur with strategic trade
policies.[172]
Protectionism and industrial policy have been profitably
used in Latin America examples being: Brazil ,
steel and aircraft; Mexico ,
motor vehicles; Chile ,
grapes, forest products, fisheries. Thirteen of the top twenty export companies
in Chile
were creations of a government agency. Despite these bright spots Latin
American industrial policies have yielded poor results when compared to East Asia . Only East Asian governments were disciplined
enough so that these measures would be used to build durable economic
capabilities and not be dissipated through short-term corruption and favoritism.
In Latin America favored interests were
allowed to stifle competition. Favored industries were over-protected and never
achieved international competitiveness; the resulting domestic orientation
could not bring in enough foreign exchange with which to purchase the most
advanced technologies. There were insufficient employment opportunities for
educated workers resulting in a brain drain.[173] Thus massive numbers of educated workers
emigrate to the U.S.
This is the dirty underside of the vaunted compassionate American immigration
policy; draining educated and skilled workers from their native lands.
The Mexican maquiladora experiment is an example of the
Latin failure to effectively employ advanced technology. “Although these plants
often consume fairly sophisticated technology, in the form of imported capital
equipment, what they do with technology is not especially sophisticated. So the
Mexican economy accumulates neither human nor any other kind of capital; the
products there have no scale economies at the assembly stage.”[174]
This resulted in Mexican jobs going to China. Nevertheless these efforts,
resulting from a free trade agreement, seem to be producing enough semiskilled
manual labor to massively displace American workers with, primarily, illegal
immigrants.
The U.S.
has also had an industrial policy in two areas in particular. In agriculture
government agencies have sponsored research and disseminated knowledge of
innovations. There were also a number of large scale government projects
particularly in irrigation. Defense projects have always been a major source of
research; in recent times the facilitation of innovation and of scale economies
in military technology has had wide spillover effects, particularly into
civilian aircraft.
Aviation is just one example of an industry nurtured by
government military spending.
The internet developed from military research resulting
in ARPANET. The semiconductor industry developed out of the transistor invented
by Bell Laboratories in 1947. Bell Labs
was part of AT&T, a government sanctioned monopoly which could only afford
such a facility because it was shielded from the completive market. The U.S.
Government subsidized the semiconductor industry from the start. Almost its
entire product in the early years was bought by the government for military
use. Other U.S.
government agencies, in modern times, were also active in initiating the
development of new industries. The biotech industry has resulted from NSF and
NIH funding.
The Sputnik effect was an important factor in military
spurred industrial development. During the Cold War the need to beat the Soviet Union was paramount. However, when the Cold War
ended, serious industrial policy also seems to have ended. After the fall of
the Berlin Wall President Bush, destroyed the CIA created Project Socrates
which was designed to develop industrial policies and economic insights to
reverse America ’s
declining economic and technological competitiveness. And as we have seen
buying strategically important products from America became less important than
getting those more cheaply abroad. Moreover, some staff members of this project
then put their knowledge to use for the benefit of foreign competitors.
Furthermore there are now counterfeit electronic components in military systems
opening up the possibility of sabotage. We also face politically inspired
supply disruptions as in the case of Swiss company Micro Crystal AG which
refused to supply timing crystals for smart bombs during the Iraq war.[175]
At this time there is now a similar situation with respect to space under the
Obama administration; the U.S.
relies on Russia
for its access to manned space flight. Unfortunately, the pragmatic viewpoint
on protecting the industrial interests of the U.S. that characterized President
Reagan has not been shared by any of his four successors.
There have always been many instances of American
industrial policy. In the 19th century railroads, canals and telegraphs all
depended on direct or indirect support from the federal or local governments.
Later utilities, highways and air transport facilities were created under
direct or indirect government sponsorship. In addition there are also export
processing zones where companies receive duty free access to imported
materials, tax subsidies, subsidized infrastructure and selected exemption from
regulations. Individual states also have a long record of industrial policy
with special economic and high tech zones, tax concessions, subsidies and
infrastructure. These are often used to keep existing companies or attract new
ones, sometimes of foreign origin.
However there are no signs of intelligent industrial policies
at the present time. As Fletcher observes the Obama stimulus package:
… included money for every Congressional pork barrel
under the sun, but nothing for one of the industrial-policy programs with the
best record of saving and creating jobs, the Manufacturing Extension
Partnership, despite campaign promises to double the program’s funding. This
program maintains a network of centers in every state designed to help American
manufacturers adopt innovative technologies. …
As a result of America ’s
neglect of industrial policy, there is a starvation of basic and applied
research in areas such as biocomputing, computer architecture, software,
optoelectronics, aeronautics, advanced materials, factory automation, sensors,
energy conversion and storage, nanomanufacturing, and robotics.[176]
Trade Agreements
There is much room for improvement in the areas of trade
relations and trade agreements. Trade policies and agreements must take account
of labor conditions, environmental standards, hidden subsidies and currency
manipulation and provide for true reciprocity. In recent years most of the
deficit was with China , Japan , Canada ,
Mexico and Germany . Bilateral agreements therefore that are
enforced are preferable to more nebulous international regulations. In
particular, any future North American partnerships must avoid the NAFTA
mistakes and provide for high environmental standards, humane labor conditions,
and cooperation on immigration enforcement. Transparency in these agreements is
also required. “Obsessive official concealment has allowed a succession of
presidents to make covert agreements with other countries on matters of great importance,
including the trading away of hundreds of U.S. industries and millions of
good-paying jobs for dubious ideological and foreign policy objectives.”[177]
Transparency in government would also be beneficial. Trade enforcement should
be separated from the function of trade negotiation so as to preclude conflicts
of interest. Senior officials should have to file income and employment
statements for a period of time after leaving office and for ex-presidents it
should be a lifetime requirement. The payment of millions of dollars to such
high officials by foreign interests should be regarded as a delayed bribe for
some action taken while in office. Open disclosure is the best remedy for such
abuses. An independent ethics body overlooking Congress would also be a way of
increasing transparency into the actions of members.[178]
The Value-Added Tax, commonly used in Europe
is the source of an unfair trade practice. Most European nations provide full
VAT rebates on their exports and impose VAT equivalent taxes on imports from
the U.S. Congress should impose an equalizing fee on imports and an equalizing
rebate on U.S. exports to these countries. Current WTO rules make such
equalizing taxes impossible for manufactured goods but services are another
story and such action could be the opening gambit for bringing this issue into
negotiations.[179]
Other initiatives America needs to take to remain a
competitive nation include strengthening its patents system and exercising its
right under the WTO to bring cases and seek damages against nations that fail
in their WTO obligations.[180] Still another is to adopt in a manner
consistent with WTO rules, "buy domestic” procurement requirements related
to all federal purchases especially those associated with new investment in
infrastructure; as of now America
is the only nation among the major developed nations without such a program.[181]
Product Safety Regulation
Law and regulation is an important adjunct to trade
policy. More stringent regulations providing for informed consumer choice and
to prevent the importation of dangerous products should be a high priority.
Congress should require country of origin labeling for foodstuffs and related
products and should give the FDA and USDA resources for more regular
inspections of foreign plants along with an inspection fee on imported foods
and medicines to finance these activities. Importers, distributors and
retailers bringing dangerous goods to market should be held accountable.
Certificates of authenticity and safety backed by bonding should be required in
the event that the imported product proves dangerous. And countries with a
record of exporting such goods should be put on special mandated inspections
list. Federal agencies should also be required to disclose their findings on a
timely basis.[182]
Regarding product safety foreign manufacturers may have
one great advantage in that they can evade U.S. liability laws:
They can effectively limit their total liability for
their U.S.
operations by the cold-blooded expedient of keeping few of their assets in this
country. Transnational recognition of judgment rules are still cumbersome
enough to provide an effective shield against the wholesale export of U.S.
liability verdicts to collect against the foreign-based assets of a foreign
firm, no matter where its products may have been marketed.[183]
It is incumbent on Congress and regulators to devise
remedies for such evasion perhaps with trade penalties for offending nations
that refuse to provide for honest and effective legal systems.
Smart Globalism
Above all an intelligent, subtle and adaptable trade
policy is required. Michael Porter captures the essence of such a policy:
Trade policy must focus on unfair subsidies and
trade barriers, and counter them with compensating tariffs and restrictions on
industry investment in the United
States by the nation’s competitors until
foreign practices are modified. At the same time, antirust scrutiny must guard
domestic competition. … Relative to most nations, the United States
has a cumbersome structure for formulating and implementing trade policy. Too
many federal agencies, with inconsistent goals are involved.[184]
Fletcher also calls for such a “smart” globalism
contending that economic nationalism can be a technocratic and forward-looking
force and stating that “it is important to guard against calling for
protectionism merely to save dying industries … trying to keep a primitive
labor-intensive industry … will just squander money that would have been better
spent defending an industry in which America has a fighting chance. Or breaking
into an entirely new sunrise industry.”[185]
Given that any industry has a life cycle no job will last forever. VCRs, once a
sunrise industry are now a sunset one. An effective defense of the U.S.
industrial base cannot be a static one.[186]
Cultivating
Comparative Advantage
Industrial policy and other industry protective measures
may be controversial but doing nothing is the equivalent of a
Deindustrialization policy. The loss of an industry is also a loss to its
entire supply chain with all of the accompanying complex web of skills which
have been built up over many years. There is also a loss of access to
sophisticated foreign markets and technology. Because of its assumption that
market prices will always send the correct signals and because it does not take
adequate account of externalities free market economics ignores these emergent
properties aspects of the economy. In recent decades America has had to endure the loss
of many cutting-edge high technology industries along with their long supply
chains. The loss of the VCR industry meant the loss of the ability to
participate in more sophisticated video recording equipment. Similarly, the
loss of the consumer electronic camera market led to the loss of the
professional camera market. The U.S.
is losing its position in semiconductors to the nations of East Asia; in 2008
only 19% of investment was in North America; 72% was in East
Asia . America
has lost its position in photolithographic steppers which print
micro-electronic computer circuits on silicon chips. The collaboration between
the makers and users of these machines which has in the past driven innovation
is now difficult in the U.S.
The printed circuit board industry in the U.S.
has also been migrating to in East Asia . All
of this means that future industries arising from these innovations and their
accompanying skill base will take place abroad. A similar chain of events in
the past happened to Britain
with its inventions of radar, passenger jets and CAT scanners being lost to the
U.S. Foreign oligopoly
producers can be expected to favor their own corporate partners as the first
served on a supply chain. This could turn into a weapon used against American
industry. Japan ’s
control of advanced battery technology will give it an overwhelming advantage
in the rising and recently much touted electric automobile industry.[187]
Another blow to that anticipated source of American jobs recently occurred when
the Obama administration’s favorite manufacturing company GE recently transferred
key facilities to China .
The deleterious chain effects of the loss of a product,
particularly one that is high technology and state of the art should never be
discounted. A whole complex of complementary manufacturing production may be
affected. For example a computer chip must be used in conjunction with
development systems, boards, emulators and marketing efforts. “Computer hardware must have software
available, autos must have gasoline, textbooks must have examination copies,
and copiers need copier paper and service.” Innovators, as well as economists
and trade negotiators may easily underestimate the importance of these
complementarities which turn a mere device into a marketable product.
Complementarities on the supplier side may also exist on the level of
distribution, marketing and product support.[188]
A number of other factors accompany and contribute to the
downward spiral of deindustrialization. There is a loss of comparative
advantages with the deterioration of human skills and falling behind in science
and technology relative to other nations. Local needs can fall out of sync with
global demand, e.g. Americans continuing demand for large cars delayed the U.S. auto
industry’s response to foreign car manufacturers. In addition an entrenched management
may be unable to adjust to changing conditions or make the necessary Investment
in R&D. This is accompanied by a waning of domestic rivalry with its
pressure to improve and adapt to change.[189]
Domestic rivalry puts pressure on firms to innovate, lower costs and improve
quality. It also toughens firms up to compete with foreign rivals and sell
abroad. Increasing foreign sales then leads the firm to attain even greater
economies of scale.[190]
The key to success in any policies is that comparative
advantage requires cultivation. This
means moving from advantages based merely on the endowment of factors toward
one based on creating new factors of production. The following passage from the
perspective of a Brazilian left wing economist concerned about third world
progress is true and generally applicable to all nations:
A single-minded insistence on the maximization of
free trade gives too little weight to an imperative that turns out to be of
vital, indeed of increasing significance: the need of every country, richer or
poorer, to avoid lasting confinement to a particular place in the international
division of labor and to the styles of production, the strategies of
development, and the sets of institutions that may exert this confining
influence.[191]
Porter adds the following important addition: “Every
industry is unique and has its own unique structure. … Structurally attractive
industries” are those with sustainable entry barriers in technology, skills,
and brand reputation. A nation’s standard of living depends on its ability to
enter or acquire such structurally attractive industries.[192]
Therefore factor creation is one of the most important
prerequisites for the international competitiveness of a nation. Furthermore,
The factors most important to competitive advantage
in most industries, especially the industries most vital to productivity growth
in advanced economies, are not inherited but are created within a nation,
through processes that differ widely across nations and among industries. Thus,
the stock of factors at any particular time is less important than the rate at
which they are created, upgraded, and made more specialized to particular
industries.[193]
Factor creating mechanisms come in a variety of forms
including education, industry research facilities, and infrastructure. These
require continual investment in maintenance and upgrading; the more advanced
and specialized the factor the greater is its continuing maintenance cost. Nor
is it necessarily solely government that is best equipped in the task of factor
creation. The direct participation by
firms, trade associations, and individuals is required. Private and public
investment and development strategy should be closely coordinated for the
nurturing of globally competitive national industries.[194]
Ironically it is often a disadvantage in basic factors
that motivates nations and firms to create higher forms of comparative
advantage. In addition an abundance of factors, such as a large endowment of a
particular natural resource may cause a nation to defer acquiring the
technology needed for creating advanced factors. The example of Switzerland is
illustrative. By holding back immigration in the post World War 2 period, Switzerland ,
unlike its neighbors, was motivated to seek advanced factors to upgrade its
labor productivity.[195]
Competitive advantage in one industry can ripple up and
down the supply chain conferring advantages on a host of related industries.
“National success in an industry is particularly likely if the nation has
competitive success in a number of related industries.”[195]
Sophisticated and technologically advanced business customers, as well as
consumers, are important in pulling up the level of whole industries. This
virtuous circle of industry upgrading cannot always be generated by the
workings of the free market; it is inherently a process dependent on
externalities. These externalities are taken for granted in the
business/financial structures of Asia and the family networks in Italy which
capture these ladder externalities and the associated profits. Climbing this ladder of industry
externalities is an example of dependence on path. An economy must enter new industries with the
right “driver” technologies with spinoffs on many other technologies along the
industry’s supply chain. Advanced driver technologies along with industries
having economies of scale mark the distinction between a First World economy
and a Third World one.[197]
Driver technologies and economies of scale have particularly characterized
advanced electronics where a radically new chip design provokes a torrent of
new technologies being assembled into new products in large scale production
facilities.
Thus, it is the case that some industries are superior to
others. Landes contends that an examination of the historical record shows that
the gains from trade are unequal. “The primary reason is that comparative
advantage is not the same for all, and that some activities are more lucrative
and productive than others.”[198]
Good industries produce goods capable of infinite improvement as in computers
or aircraft; bad industries produce goods of fixed character as in produce or
underwear. Good industries are susceptible to innovation and product
differentiation which enables them to establish strong competitive positions with
little vulnerability to competition from cheap foreign labor. The strong
economic positions characteristic of firms in such industries is accompanied by
rising worker purchasing power which then spurs further industrial development.[199]
Bad industries, on the other hand, are characterized by
diminishing rather than increasing returns and dead-end jobs. Agriculture, raw
materials extraction and, more recently, unskilled manufacturing are examples.
Good and bad industry categories are dynamic. The textile industry was good for
developed nations like Britain
two hundred years ago but is not so today. These industries either migrate to
less developed areas or stagnate. These stagnant industries, personal service
for example, also perform essential functions.
However when a nation possesses an abundance of good industries its
economy will be stronger and its growth prospects will be better.[200]
One example illustrating the fruitfulness of a “good” industry is that of U.S. medical
innovations. The U.S.
is “such a favorable environment for commercializing medical innovations that
dozens of American entrepreneurs sprang up in most new product and service
areas. In fact, foreign entrepreneurs have come to the United States to start their
medical products companies because it is such a hospitable environment for this
particular sector.”[201]
The U.S. was able to enjoy such an innovative medical industry as a result of
its keeping a relatively free domestic market which has allowed new ideas, some
even once regarded as unconventional, to eventually find their way into the
medical canon. The recent comprehensive health reform legislation might well
mark the end of that innovativeness.
A popular advertising slogan states that an “educated
consumer is the best customer.” That applies just as well to attaining
competitive advantage. “A nation’s firms gain competitive advantage if domestic
buyers are, or are among the world’s most sophisticated and demanding buyers
for the product or service. … Sophisticated and demanding buyers pressure local
firms to meet high standards in terms of product quality, features and
service.”[202]
For example Japan ’s
knowledgeable consumers gave a great advantage to Japanese firms’ development
of cutting edge audio equipment. The beneficial effects of sophisticated
domestic consumers include a large home market size and economies of scale and
a high rate of growth of home demand leading to the rapid adoption of
innovations. The development of a large domestic market will spur product
improvement preparing the way for acceptance abroad.[203]
Porter notes how the decline in sophistication of Americans has adversely
impacted the U.S.
competitive position:
American consumers are often no longer the most
affluent. They are certainly not the most demanding. They tolerate products and
services that no Japanese or German would. This observation was made time after
time in our interviews with executives, frequently American executives.[204]
As indicated in Chapter 1 there has been a marked decline
in U.S.
educational standards and a neglect of the more gifted students. The coarsening
of American consumer tastes is one symptom of this trend. Another is the
shortage of trained technical workers. The experience of Britain as compared with that of Germany is instructive; with the British economy
underperforming relative to that of Germany . British education deemphasizes math and
science, and reinforces British tendencies toward personal non-competitiveness.
In Germany
technical colleges have high status, and there is a well-developed
apprenticeship system.[205]
In the U.S.
it is the eroding quality of human resources relative to other nations that is
an important factor impeding technological competitiveness. Porter remarks on
the causes and results of America ’s
failing educational system:
American schools set low standards and are weak in
discipline. American high school graduates are well behind those in other
advanced nations in training in vital areas such as math, science and
languages. Japanese firms building U.S. plants have found, for example, that
the statistical techniques involved in statistical process control, which can
be understood by most Japanese high school graduates, are a complete mystery to
many American college graduates.
There is no well developed apprenticeship system, no
strong vocational school system, no Italian-style tradition of working in an
industry for generations, and no Japanese-style emphasis on in-company
training.
With less sophisticated workers, and often less
technically trained managers as well, American firms will no longer represent
the most advanced and cutting-edge needs. American workers were not capable in
a number of industries we studied of using the most sophisticated foreign-made
equipment. Special simpler models had to be created for the American market. … There is a diversion of top talent in America
away from industry. Top graduates have flocked into law, medicine, and finance,
not into technical fields.”[206]
Education as well as as well as broader cultural factors impact
national competitiveness. While the market is the most efficient method of
organizing an economy there is no guarantee that people will respond timely or
well to market signals. “Some people do this better than others, and culture
can make all the difference. … Some people find it easier and more agreeable
to take than to make.”[207]
The impact of human resources and of culture leads
naturally into a consideration of immigration. Mass immigration affects more
than just the quality of the student and worker population. The rapid increase
in population resulting from large-scale mass immigration affects energy
consumption. When combined with the failure to deal with fuel efficiency the
increase in U.S.
dependence on unreliable foreign oil represents an obvious security problem in
addition to its balance of trade impact. Our crumbling infrastructure, another
area with a large immigration connection also has deleterious effects on U.S. competitiveness.
The next chapter examines the effect recent immigration has had on accelerating
U.S.
economic decline.
[116] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 556.
[117]
Ibid, p. 559.
[118]
Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, p. 33.
[119]
Ibid, p. 48.
[120]
Ibid, pp. 39-42.
[121]
Samuelson, The Good Life and its Discontents, p. 44.
[122]
Landes, Wealth and Poverty of Nations, p. 473.
[123]
Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, p. 128.
[124]
Landes, Wealth and Poverty of Nations, p. 172.
[125]
Carlo Cipolla, Before the Industrial Revolution, New York , Norton, 1976, pp. 234-35.
[126]
Ibid, p. 235.
[127]
Ibid, p. 61.
[128]
Ibid, p. 244.
[129]
Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 520.
[130]
Landes, Wealth and Poverty of Nations, p. 489.
[131]
Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, pp. 69-70.
[132]
Ibid, p. 68.
[133]
Ibid, p. 177.
[134]
Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, pp. 524-25.
[135]
Ibid, p. 525.
[136]
Choate, Dangerous Business, pp. 16-18.
[137]
Ibid, p. 121.
[138]
Samuelson, The Great Inflation and its Aftermath, pp. 222-23.
[139]
Choate, Hot Property, p. 91.
[140]
Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, pp. 27-28.
[141]
Choate, Dangerous Business, p. 79.
[142]
Ibid, p. 86.
[143]
Ibid, pp. 58-59.
[144]
Ibid, pp. 61-62.
[145]
Ibid, pp. 41-42.
[146]
Ibid, p. 43.
[147]
Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, p. 178.
[148]
Choate, Dangerous Business, p. 84.
[149]
Ibid, p. 201.
[150] Choate, Hot Property, p. 176.
[151] Scott Wheeler, http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m1571/is_40_18/ai_94511263/
[152] Choate, Hot Property, pp. 173-177.
[153] Choate, Dangerous Business, p. 175.
[154] Ibid, pp. 22-23.
[155] Ibid, p. 175.
[156 Among many sources reporting on this story are: Tait Trussell, “Brazilian Oil and Re-election Schemes”, frontpagemag.com, 1/16/2012, Stephen Pope, “Hawker Beech Sues to Block Embraer Air Force Contract” , www.flyingmag.com, Jan 03, 2012 and Jeff Head, “Obama Admin informs Beechcraft of aircraft loss in favor of Brazilian firm with ties to Iran”, Washington Examiner Nov 21, 2011.
[157] Steve Stecklow, “Special Report: Chinese firm helpsIran spy on citizens, Reuters, Mar 22, 2012.
[158] http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/worldnews/northamerica/usa/8876656/US-weapons-full-of-fake-Chinese-parts.html
[159] Choate, Dangerous Business, pp. 148-49.
[160] Choate, Hot Property, p. 83.
[161] Choate, Dangerous Business, pp. 6-13.
[162] Ibid, p. 15.
[176] Ibid, p. 211.
[177] Choate, Dangerous Business, p. 164.
[178] Ibid, pp. 169-70.
[179] Ibid, p. 189.
[180] Ibid, pp. 200-201.
[181] Leo Hindery Jr. and Leo W. Gerard,. “Our Jobless Recovery”, The Nation, July 13, 2009.
[182] Choate, Dangerous Business, pp. 179-80.
[183] Peter Huber, Liability and Insurance Problems inRosenberg , Landau and Mowery, Technology and the Wealth of Nations, p. 219.
[184] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 173.
[185] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, p. 91.
[188] David Teece, Capturing the Financial Benefits from Technological Innovation inRosenberg , Landau and Mowery, Technology and the Wealth of Nations, pp. 183-85.
[189] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, pp. 166-69.
[190] Ibid, pp. 117-122.
[191] Roberto Unger, Free Trade Reimagined,Princeton University Press, 2007, p. 2.
[192] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 36.
[195] Ibid, p. 83.
[196] Ibid, p. 107.
[197] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, pp. 185-191.
[198] Landes, Wealth and Poverty of Nations, p. 522.
[199] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, p. 192.
[200] Ibid, pp. 193-95.
[201] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 126.
[202] Ibid, p. 89.
[203] Ibid, pp. 93-97.
[204] Ibid, p. 522.
[205] Ibid, p. 497.
[206] Ibid, pp. 520-27.
[207] Landes, Wealth and Poverty of Nations, p. 522.
[150] Choate, Hot Property, p. 176.
[151] Scott Wheeler, http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m1571/is_40_18/ai_94511263/
[152] Choate, Hot Property, pp. 173-177.
[153] Choate, Dangerous Business, p. 175.
[154] Ibid, pp. 22-23.
[155] Ibid, p. 175.
[156 Among many sources reporting on this story are: Tait Trussell, “Brazilian Oil and Re-election Schemes”, frontpagemag.com, 1/16/2012, Stephen Pope, “Hawker Beech Sues to Block Embraer Air Force Contract” , www.flyingmag.com, Jan 03, 2012 and Jeff Head, “Obama Admin informs Beechcraft of aircraft loss in favor of Brazilian firm with ties to Iran”, Washington Examiner Nov 21, 2011.
[157] Steve Stecklow, “Special Report: Chinese firm helps
[158] http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/worldnews/northamerica/usa/8876656/US-weapons-full-of-fake-Chinese-parts.html
[159] Choate, Dangerous Business, pp. 148-49.
[160] Choate, Hot Property, p. 83.
[161] Choate, Dangerous Business, pp. 6-13.
[162] Ibid, p. 15.
[163] The following history of trade is derived from these sources:
Sidney Homer and Richard Sylla, A History of Interest Rates, 1991
David Landes, Wealth and Poverty of Nations, 1999
Carlo Cipolla, Before the Industrial Revolution, 1976
Ian Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, 2010
Carolyn Webber and Aaron Wildavsky, A History of Taxation and Expenditure in the Western World, 1986
Pat Choate, Hot Property, 2005
Pat Choate, Dangerous Business, 2008
In Sima Lieberman, Europe and the Industrial Revolution, 1972:
Wolfram Fischer, Government Activity and Industrialization in Germany (1815-70)
David Landes, French Entrepreneurship and Industrial Growth in the 19th Century
Rondo Cameron, Economic Growth and Stagnation in France , 1815-1914
Jane Jacobs, Cities and the Wealth of Nations, 1985
Douglass North, Economic Growth of the United States 1790-1860, 1966
Robert Samuelson, The Great Inflation and its Aftermath, 2008
Margaret Myers, A Financial History of the United States , 1970
Sidney Ratner, James Soltow and Richard Sylla, Evolution of the American Economy, 1979
[164] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, pp. 233-34.
[165] Hat tip to businessman Wayne Conti for suggesting this term.
[167] Samuelson, The Good Life and its Discontents, p. 41.
[168] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, pp. 72-73.
[169] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 675.[168] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, pp. 72-73.
[176] Ibid, p. 211.
[177] Choate, Dangerous Business, p. 164.
[178] Ibid, pp. 169-70.
[179] Ibid, p. 189.
[180] Ibid, pp. 200-201.
[181] Leo Hindery Jr. and Leo W. Gerard,. “Our Jobless Recovery”, The Nation, July 13, 2009.
[182] Choate, Dangerous Business, pp. 179-80.
[183] Peter Huber, Liability and Insurance Problems in
[184] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 173.
[185] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, p. 91.
[188] David Teece, Capturing the Financial Benefits from Technological Innovation in
[189] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, pp. 166-69.
[190] Ibid, pp. 117-122.
[191] Roberto Unger, Free Trade Reimagined,
[192] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 36.
[195] Ibid, p. 83.
[196] Ibid, p. 107.
[197] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, pp. 185-191.
[198] Landes, Wealth and Poverty of Nations, p. 522.
[199] Fletcher, Free Trade Doesn’t Work, p. 192.
[200] Ibid, pp. 193-95.
[201] Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations, p. 126.
[202] Ibid, p. 89.
[203] Ibid, pp. 93-97.
[204] Ibid, p. 522.
[205] Ibid, p. 497.
[206] Ibid, pp. 520-27.
[207] Landes, Wealth and Poverty of Nations, p. 522.
No comments:
Post a Comment