Saturday, September 14, 2013

Conclusion


Chapter 7

Conclusion


 

As we have seen the one thing that above all else characterizes the new economic order is an outright war waged against the great American middle; the middle class and the productive working class. The new ideologies underlying the transformation of America arose in the turbulent period of the 1960s and early 1970s. Ironically it was the very great affluence of postwar America that supported the social programs and also provided sinecures for the social critics who pressed for the ever expanding list of entitlements and diversity-promoting regulations. The new elite, now turned into a permanent governing class, share a common globalist vision; that being one of equality, diversity, multiculturalism and globalism. Commitment to this vision unites all factions of the elite: ex-radicals, old-fashioned liberals and “compassionate conservatives”. Enforcers of the new orthodoxy, the mainstream media, are quick to attack any who dare question the prevailing ideology. Despite, or indeed because, of the ideology of diversity and equality the gap between those at the top and those at the bottom has increased greatly and the U.S. economy has been progressively hollowed out. The financial collapse and great recession has been one result.

 

Lessons Not Learned


 

Nothing deters the new ruling elite from their disastrous economic course; not even the largest terrorist attack to occur on American soil. The 911 terrorist attacks did not keep business, and banking, as usual from quickly resuming. FBI Assistant Director Steve McCraw testified before the House Subcommittee on Immigration, Border Security and Claims on June 26, 2003 that the matricula cards issued by the government of Mexico were not a reliable proof of identity. But that had not kept Bank of America from accepting those cards as valid ID for mortgages and various other loans. As Assistant Director McCraw testified:

 

These criminal threats are significant, but it is the terrorist threat presented by the Matricula Consular that is most worrisome. Federal officials have discovered individuals from many different countries in possession of the Matricula Consular card. Most of these individuals are citizens of other Central or South American countries. However, at least one individual of Middle Eastern descent has also been arrested in possession of the Matricula Consular card. The ability of foreign nationals to use the Matricula Consular to create a well-documented, but fictitious, identity in the U.S. provides an opportunity for terrorists to move freely within the U.S. without triggering name-based watch lists that are disseminated to local police officers. It also allows them to board planes without revealing their true identity. All of these threats are in addition to the transfer of terrorist funds, mentioned earlier.[1]

 

Michael Cutler, onetime INS Senior Special Agent, observes that:

 

It is unthinkable that, after the clear and convincing warning issued by the head of FBI intelligence at a Congressional hearing conducted approximately 20 months after the worst terrorist attack ever committed on American soil, and arguably the worst terrorist attack of modern history, bankers summarily ignored that advice! Clearly these bankers do not say a pledge of allegiance to the red, white, and blue flag of the U.S. but to a banner, likely green in color, festooned with dollar signs![2]

 

Of course, bankers, regulators and government policymakers have also been ignoring warnings about an impending financial disaster for many years before and since 2001.

 

Such cluelessness is evident even at the present day. The Republican leadership provides a case study in obtuseness and wishful thinking. The demographic changes resulting from immigration that have ushered them from power have apparently left no impression on the minds of the top echelon of the Party. Republican leaders plead for the party to accommodate itself to the concerns of all groups but one; that one being the white working class. The latter have seen their jobs exported and they and their children are forced to compete with low wage immigrant labor for the ones that remain. They are also the ones that must bear the burden for the social policies pushed by the insulated elite.

 

A study by political quant Sean Trende shows that the 2012 elections actually weren’t about a demographic explosion with non-white voters. Instead, they were about a large group of white voters not showing up.” He observes that while there were increases in the Black and Hispanic vote, these were “dwarfed by the decline in the number of whites.” Looking at the critical swing state of Ohio Trende notes the following:

 

We can see that the counties clustered around Columbus in the center of the state turned out in full force, as did the suburban counties near Cincinnati in the southwest. These heavily Republican counties are the growing areas of the state, filled with white-collar workers.

 

Where things drop off are in the rural portions of Ohio, especially in the southeast. These represent areas still hard-hit by the recession. Unemployment is high there, and the area has seen almost no growth in recent years.

 

My sense is these voters were unhappy with Obama. But his negative ad campaign relentlessly emphasizing Romney’s wealth and tenure at Bain Capital may have turned them off to the Republican nominee as well. The Romney campaign exacerbated this through the challenger’s failure to articulate a clear, positive agenda to address these voters’ fears, and self-inflicted wounds like the “47 percent” gaffe. Given a choice between two unpalatable options, these voters simply stayed home.[3]

 

We may reasonably conclude that the white voters who did not show up to vote Republican are those who have suffered the most from the policies pushed by the ruling elite over the last four decades.

 

Economics and Reality


 

Many economists, particularly those of a free market conservative or libertarian persuasion, continue to cling to outmoded economic theory regarding trade and immigration. They discount the importance of meta-economics – the underlying structure supporting the economic system, culture, law, the social contract and human capital. Liberals including some liberal economists believe that the American people cling to their murderous guns and outmoded religion and should be punished. Similarly, many of their conservative counterparts believe that the American people cling to their belief in fair labor practices, a social safety net and social security. Thus, according to the likes of the Wall Street Journal and Cato Institute libertarians, they must be punished by having their jobs deported while being replaced by a new and, presumably, more pliant population. These along with many in the Republican establishment are advocates for free trade and open borders.

 

Besides the deterioration in the U.S. standard of living, the hollowing out of manufacturing promoted borrowing and financial speculation. The recycling of U.S. dollars at low interest rates back into the economy by America’s foreign competitors financed U.S. importing and consumption and fed America’s massive increase in debt.[4] Following the examples of NAFTA and CAFTA the free traders are now pushing for a Free Trade Area of the Americas which would impose tariff reductions and trade controls encompassing almost the entire Western Hemisphere. As we have seen such ill-considered trade agreements have often turned out to be one-sided. High technology CEO Richard Elkus points out how America has been shut out of future industries:

 

Just as the loss of the VCR wiped out America’s ability to participate in the design and manufacture of broadcast video-recording equipment, the loss of the design and manufacturing of consumer electronic cameras in the United States virtually guaranteed the demise of its professional camera market....Thus, as the United States lost its position in consumer electronics, it began to lose its competitive base in commercial electronics as well. The losses in these related infrastructures would begin to negatively affect other downstream industries, not the least of which was the automobile.[5]

 

Mr. Elkus then says something of supreme importance emphasizing the organic nature of an economy; an inconvenient fact too often not acknowledged by economists of all political persuasions. “Like an ecosystem, a competitive economy is a holistic entity, far greater than the sum of its parts.”[6]

 

Open Borders Conservatives

 

It is hard to understand the obsession free-market conservative and libertarian economists have with open borders and mass immigration; particularly when one considers how the rapid demographic consequences are effectively shutting them out of political influence. Typical representatives of this species of thought are the Cato Institute’s Daniel Griswold and Jason Riley of the Wall Street Journal. The ruins of the World Trade Center were still smoldering when Griswold rose to the defense of the very immigration status quo that had eased the way for the terrorists. Griswold attacked several writers at National Review as "anti-immigrant crusaders" who seized the opportunity to “whip up hostility to immigration." He then turned on a new Border Patrol anti-crime initiative viewing it as “just another example of government trying to stop people from doing something that is natural, to better their conditions." John Fonte of the Hudson Institute observes that Griswold’s position is not representative of classical libertarianism as exemplified by the Nobel Prize-winning economist Frederich A. Hayek “who stood first and foremost for the rule of law and “would surely have repudiated an extreme laissez-faire dogmatism that argues that a free society should not establish and enforce rules to regulate the admission of non-citizens.” In addition “Griswold's position expresses utter contempt for American democracy and the principles of republican self-government.”[7] Griswold and his colleagues at the Cato Institute assert that the problem is not one of immigration but rather that of the welfare state. As we have seen above, immigrants, even those here illegally, are able to avail themselves of many welfare benefits. Robert Rector of the Heritage Foundation eviscerates this libertarian viewpoint:

 

While most open-border libertarians proclaim a desire to dismantle both borders and the welfare state, in practice what they offer is open borders today and a vague (and almost certainly illusory) promise to end the welfare state in the indefinite future. As Milton Friedman understood, open-border enthusiasts have the sequence wrong: Opening borders with the redistributionist state still intact will result in a larger and more confiscatory government. In response to libertarians who propose to open borders and dismantle the welfare state, practical conservatives should answer: “Go ahead. Dismantle the welfare state. As soon as you’ve got that finished, let us know, and then we’ll talk about open borders.”[8]

 

Jason Riley, a member of the Wall Street Journal editorial board also argues the case for unrestricted immigration. A review of Riley’s book, Let Them In, appeared in the Wall Street Journal which summarized his major themes.[9] Looking at what he calls the work-force effect Riley asserts that immigrants fall into two groups, the low-skilled and the highly educated with American workers falling between these extremes. Thus immigrants “tend not to elbow aside natives for jobs and depress wages.” As many studies have shown (see Chapter 3) this contention is simply wrong; in fact there are many U.S. workers both at the lower and higher end who have lost out to immigrant labor. Moreover given the dumbing down of the U.S. education system the suspicion arises that many high school graduates and even those with some college are really in the low-skilled labor category. It is an irony that this was written at the beginning of 2008 when unemployment began its rise to 8% and above with the real rate being in double digits. One may suspect that Riley still holds to the same opinion today since the Wall Street Journal view is echoed by a GOP establishment pushing their own amnesty and skilled worker immigration proposals.

 

Riley’s next concern is with the “talent imperative”. He casts blame on the teachers' unions for the dreadful condition of American public education. It is easy and convenient to blame teachers while ignoring the quality of the student body and particularly the significant burden placed on the system by the flood of non-English speaking immigrant underclass children. He worries that without talented employees from India and China Bill Gates will not be able to keep Microsoft competitive. To keep the American lead in science and technology it is “better to let Apple and Google and eBay make their own personnel decisions without interference”. Of course he does not consider the alteration of immigration laws so that Gates can employ low-cost software engineers “interference”. Riley is another free-market advocate who evinces a woeful lack of confidence in the ability of the market to adjust. He does not acknowledge the price signal given by the labor market; a rise in wages will induce additional entry. In the past many workers in high tech have had backgrounds in engineering or science not directly related to computer technology; a rise in wages will induce many of these to enter the market. A rise in wages will also encourage talented students to shift their studies from law or finance to high technology.

 

He also contends that the true costs of illegal immigration are negligible; that in fact illegal workers produce a net surplus. He asserts that they do not have access to federal welfare benefits and are also reluctant to access emergency health care owing to a fear of apprehension and deportation. In reality, however, his alleged fear factor is simply false; illegal aliens no longer live in the shadows; indeed as shown during demonstrations and even public appearances some are quite openly and loudly visible. Emergency rooms are under great pressure due to immigrant and illegal immigrant usage. And as we have seen in Chapter 3, even if not directly eligible the children of illegal immigrants must be given access to education by law and at the same time require more expensive bilingual programs. These children also have access to numerous welfare programs. He also alleges a social security surplus since illegals pay payroll and Social Security taxes without the attendant benefits. He ignores the fact that many work off the books while others are in such low wage brackets that their contributions are minimal. As we have seen in Chapter 3 the benefits of illegal aliens accrue to their employers; the greater costs are borne by the general tax-paying public.

 

Riley warns of the political danger immigration restrictionism presents to his fellow conservatives. Given the large and increasing Hispanic population and a more generally tolerant electorate Republicans and conservatives are certain to lose out. This of course ignores the fact that the current demographic trends are not a law of nature but were deliberately engineered, and the engineers included conservatives just like Riley. Thus the arguments used by Riley and other open borders advocates are analogous to those of the man who murders his parents and seeks leniency because he is an orphan. Such conservatives neither acknowledge their responsibility nor apologize for their mistakes; they simply berate others for various forms of bigotry. Moreover McCain, one of the most pro-immigration politicians of either party, did very poorly with the Hispanic vote. California was once a middle of the road swing state, now it is permanently lost due to immigration; apparently Riley wants the same for the rest of the country. Bush and Rove appeased Hispanics in every possible way and yet the GOP is lucky when it gets even a third of their vote. For such conservatives mass immigration is similar to the business which loses money on every unit sold but seeks to make it up on volume.

 

Riley’s response to the “policy challenge” of illegal immigration is to provide “more legal ways for immigrants to enter the country.” Of course an easy way to reduce illegal immigration is to simply make everyone who enters legal; problem solved. Latino immigrants are “economic migrants” and should not be painted as “violent criminals or Islamofascists”. His incoherence here is striking; his statement implies that he only wants Latino immigrants and would discriminate against Middle Easterners. He would allow mass immigration from Latin America while banning it from even those few Muslim countries that are still friendly to the U.S. One might suspect that he is not really in favor of such blatant discrimination and his defense of Hispanic immigrants is simply a cover for the real agenda which is to “let them all in”. Disingenuously he states that “post 9/11, knowing who's in the country has rightly taken on an urgency.” But if we let all in who want to come here (except presumably Muslims?) what will be the costs of monitoring them to make sure they are not terrorists’ or criminals? Do we have the administrative apparatus in place for that? What increase in the size of government will be necessary to make sure that the millions Riley would allow in meet the standards? Of course one might suspect that he doesn’t want any real monitoring at all and if so what does that say about his alleged concern of knowing who is in the country?

 

Mac Johnson at Human Events concisely summarizes the flaws in the Wall Street Journal position on open borders:

 

More than anything else, in my opinion, it shows that the central failing of the right-wing of the open borders lobby is viewing human beings as interchangeable parts — to be self-traded like commodities across any frontier according to the simple dictate of supply and demand.  But men and women are not some sort of sentient pork belly.  Men and women are what nations are made of.  They carry in their hearts and minds the culture and beliefs and common experiences that make one nation rich and free and another poor and corrupt.

 

When you discuss the idea of unrestricted human migration across national borders, you have to recall this.  Immigration has economic consequences, but it is not exclusively an economic issue.  It is not even primarily an economic issue.  It is primarily a social or political issue.  And when the immigration in question is illegal, then it becomes an issue of the rule of law as well.

 

Men are not widgets, and immigration affects more than just numbers in an abstract spreadsheet.  America is not merely an economic opportunity zone for all comers to profit from.  America is a homeland.  America is a home to a distinct culture and the people that created it or have been assimilated into it.  It is possible that the philosophical bookends of rightist globalism and leftist multiculturalism have squashed the instinct of that people to protect their culture and to claim the right to restrict entry into their home.  But I doubt it.[10]

 

A Liberal Economist’s View of the Financial Meltdown

 

Nobel Prize-winning economist Joseph Stiglitz has a different view of the great financial meltdown. Stiglitz is, without a doubt, one of the leading economic thinkers of the present day. And although he is quite liberal Stiglitz has at least some understanding that an economy is embedded in a larger social structure and is an organic entity, as shown in his 2002 book Globalization and its Discontents.[11]  Liberal economists tend to be a bit more skeptical when it comes to free trade but blindly follow the diversity dogma when it comes to immigration and have a stubbornly incomplete view of the most important factors underlying the mortgage meltdown and recession. Stiglitz, in the analysis of the Great Recession he presents in his recent book Freefall, demonstrates this incomplete view.

 

Stiglitz is highly critical of the bankers; some of this criticism is quite justified but much of what he writes expresses the inner contradictions inherent in the liberal globalist worldview. Referring to the cost of funds to bankers, Stiglitz asserts that had “the low-cost funds been used well, for example, if the funds had gone to support investment in new technology or expansion of enterprises, we would have had a more competitive and dynamic economy.”[12] He thereby ignores the fact that new technology expansion was limited by cheap labor via ‘free trade’ abroad and immigration at home. In an amazing example of liberal inconsistency he states that “it was easier just to hand out credit cards to anyone who breathed than to do the hard work of credit assessment and judge who was creditworthy and who was not.”[13] He is evidently out to damn the banks no matter what they did. If the banks followed his recommendation he and his liberal colleagues would have, and did indeed, condemn such ‘discrimination’. When some bankers worried about the higher interest rates that would result from repealing the 2005 bankruptcy act, Stiglitz observed: “If so, so be it: Americans have overborrowed, at great cost to society and the whole world. An incentive for saving would be all for the better.”[14] But if despite the higher rates Americans continued to borrow one might suspect that there would be complaints about greedy bankers exploiting the public. And if there were stricter regulations as to who can apply for credit in the first place liberals like Stiglitz would once again denounce unfair discrimination in the credit markets. Stiglitz notes the virtues of the traditional banking model but ignores the government mandate that was most instrumental in impelling the banks to suddenly change their business practices. This lack of curiosity regarding government housing mortgage mandates on the part of progressive economists like Stiglitz is astounding. They are the counterparts of the free market conservatives who are inclined to excuse the actions of big business and the major financial companies.

 

He advocates that government provide low interest credit to owners in distress as it has done for the large banks; there is no way one can justify denying the same benefit to all. He also notes that this fairness justified both government student loan programs and government mortgages.[15] However, while the banks may have been bad in many respects, the idea that having bureaucrats unconstrained by any bottom line considerations allocating capital is an invitation to massive corruption and favoritism; the cure is worse than the disease. For example the Federal agencies were designed to promote home ownership but were pressed into making bad decisions which ignited the housing mess. And a new financial crisis involving student loans has recently surfaced.

 

Stiglitz correctly notes that the too big to fail institutions are also too big to be managed properly. Their competitive advantage arises from their ability to engage in risky investments while obtaining political favors with consequent government subsidies.[16] What he and other liberal analysts don’t consider, when they rail against those banks too big to fail and call for breaking them up, is that only large institutions with their ability to devise new ways of passing on the resulting risk could have supported government affirmative action in the credit markets. A system consisting of a large number of small banks could not have diversified their risk and would have collapsed much earlier. These would have been replaced by a government banking system with characteristics similar to the one he decries in order to carry out such policies.

 

He also writes about the ethically challenged Angelo Mozilo of Countrywide.[17] However, he ignores the sequence of events that enabled Mozilo to embark on his schemes. It was government with its CRA enforcement effort that put the wheels into motion. Smart operators like Mozilo saw how to take advantage of this Federal initiative. His success then motivated imitators and sparked many new innovations in mortgage finance. These innovations were then extended throughout the entire mortgage market and beyond. Finally the Wall Street greed machine latched on to a potential source of new profits and the subprime takeoff began.

 

Stiglitz presents a number of proposals for the reform of the financial markets. He advocates joint and several liability of all participants on the exchanges requiring that all exchange participants put up all of their assets before accessing any taxpayer money. He then states that he suspects “that such a provision might lead to the end of the market”. He also contends that: “What is needed is a Financial Products Safety Commission. One of the tasks of such a commission would be to identify which financial products are safe enough to be held by ordinary individuals and in what circumstances.”  He advocates adding financial experts from the unions, NGOs and universities to the regulatory ranks. He favors the idea of a multiplicity of regulators even if it results in some duplication of effort. Finally he cautions against adding still more power to the failed Fed.[18] His lack of concern regarding the end of the financial exchanges seems very reactionary; does he recommend going back before the invention of the exchanges in the 16th and 17th centuries? The Financial Products Safety Commission is not a bad idea. Of course, a truly honest commission would have put an end to affirmative housing credit. In general his proposed reforms are too complex; what would suffice are transparency and the cultivation of zealous and objective professional regulators free from the foolish liberal imperatives such as those that existed at the Boston Fed.

 

Positions held by liberal economists are frequently naïve, inconsistent, contradictory and incoherent; a result of blind adherence to the liberal worldview. Stiglitz, for example, praises the life insurance model as contrasted with the insurance written on securities by AIG. He observes that “companies can get data on life expectancy by occupation, sex, income and so forth, and make an even better prediction of the person seeking insurance.”[19] This is an amazing example of the inner contradictions of the modern liberal ideology as exemplified by one of its leading economic thinkers. In the housing market the insurance failed initially at the source since the lending institutions were not permitted to take income, credit history etc. into account. One must wonder whether he thought about this when he writes so knowingly and correctly about life insurance. Typical of liberals, Stiglitz does not credit government affirmative action as a possible cause of the economic crisis. This is a point that can be argued either way, but he does not mention it at all, not even as a hypothesis to be refuted.

 

The same applies to other truths inconvenient to liberal thinkers; Stiglitz cites a number of “challenges’ facing America.”[20] He mentions global warming without a word regarding the exponential growth in population. Liberals refuse to mention the undeniable contribution of population growth to the environmental problems that so concern them. To do so would be to acknowledge that the population increase is not occurring in the white west and would inevitably raise the subject of mass immigration. He decries America’s inefficient education system without making any mention of the quality of the students or the effect of large scale immigration. He is greatly concerned about the state of higher education; he favors devoting increased resources to this as a source of needed technical skills and expertise. However, he fails to mention that American students are motivated to take ‘victims studies’ programs while leaving the useful STEM studies to foreign students. Of course he approves the fact that foreign students become permanent residents without considering that they now consume and generate pollutants like Americans; and this despite his professed concern for global warming. He praises Cuba’s reduction of its infant mortality rate. However one might expect that an economist would raise the possibility that an inordinate share of scarce medical resources devoted to a showcase area which is favored by the rulers will produce such a result.

 

Stiglitz frequently mentions the socialist nations of Western Europe; one of his favorites being that of Sweden.[21] He notes America’s lack of generosity both domestically and with foreign aid as compared to that of Europe. His disdain for his own country, typical of the 60s liberal elite, is obvious. But it is interesting that he chooses the Scandinavian countries and Western Europe as paragons, countries that have been displacing their own populations at an even greater rate than has the U.S. He also ignores the fact that Europe’s generous welfare states were made possible by the U.S. defense shield. While criticizing America’s lack of generosity to developing nations he ignores much worse cases.  For example he avoids mentioning the Gulf States and Saudi Arabia whose stingy elites, with their hidden stashes of forbidden spirits, are far worse than the U.S., even when it comes to helping their own co-religionists in distress. His admiration for Sweden is particularly ironic as it has now become the rape capital of the western world due to mass immigration. Sweden now has a rape rate of 53/100,000 compared to 29 for the U.S.[22]

 

In another example of the blinkered worldview of liberals Stiglitz bemoans the supposed fact that IMF pressure on recipient countries to cut back on spending had forced Pakistanis to send their children to “the madrassas, where they would become indoctrinated in Islamic fundamentalism”.[23] It requires Incredible naiveté to believe that most Pakistanis are wannabe Kemalists who were extremely reluctant to have their children indoctrinated into Islam and did so only when forced to as a last resort.

 

Finally, Stiglitz’ position regarding immigration is typical of many liberal economists and is quite revealing. He bemoans the fact that labor does not flow as freely as capital “except in the case of the most talented individuals”.[24] This contradicts his professed concern for the environment, for the neediest and for middle-class Americans who “have fared far worse in recent years”. He points out that between December 2007 and October 2009 the economy lost 8 million jobs. With new entrants to the labor force more than 12 million jobs would need to be created for full employment. But he says not a word about the millions of immigrants, legal and illegal, who have been added to the work force over the preceding decade; nor does he consider any possible immigration moratorium during these times of high unemployment. In an analysis of the effectiveness of stimulus programs he refers to spending on foreign contractors in Iraq as having a low multiplier but conveniently ignores the multiplier effects of remittances sent home by immigrant, including illegal, workers.[25] He expresses numerous times his opinion that government should concentrate on helping the neediest, while apparently favoring importing even more. Thus ironically he joins with his ideological adversaries, conservative free market economists, in their desire for more low-wage labor.      

 

Epilogue: Time Hath Found Us


 

The Case for Economic Nationalism

 

The theme of these chapters has been one of economic nationalism. Such economic nationalism should of course be flexible and pragmatic as has been the case through most of U.S. history. The defenders of the status quo should be confronted with the following question. We have had a virtual free trade regime with China, East Asia, and NAFTA. We have also had the largest immigration flow in history since the 1965 reform; a flow that has accelerated over the last quarter century. If these have been so beneficial, then why are we in these dire circumstances today?

 

We have also seen that both conservative and liberal economic thinkers are slaves to obsolete ideologies. Society and the economy are complex systems, organic in nature. Conservatives who worry about the unintended consequences of government programs and liberals concerned about the ecological balance should both understand that evident fact.  But apparently very many of them don’t. There are trade protectionists and immigration restrictionists in both conservative and liberal ranks; these have been relatively powerless. The inner contradictions in the worldview of both ends of the elite political spectrum abound. Liberals, for example, show more of a tendency toward protectionism. However they are in favor of bringing in large numbers of immigrants, a policy that reversed the population stabilization previously attained by American citizens.  And, of course, they advocate providing the ‘American Dream’ for these immigrants.  However, their fervently professed concern for the environment leads them to promote policies hampering U.S. manufacturing in general and energy production in particular, thereby undermining both the protection of American industry and the attainment of high living standards for their immigrant clients.

 

Given the betrayal of workers by their supposed defenders in the Democrat Party and the betrayal of principle and law as well as domestic industry by the Republicans, the time may have come to consider a third party championing economic nationalism. Such a party might be able to build up a sufficient base, possibly even a plurality to advance its agenda. Economist Alan Tonelson hints at such when he advocates a coalition of immigration and trade realists; a coalition that would span the political spectrum:

 

The president’s latest end run shows that the immigration realists’ plate will remain dauntingly full. But they should strongly consider offering a helping hand to a trade realist community clearly needing assistance. The immigration control movement itself would benefit. And strengthening the trade policy critics would help reinvigorate a U.S. economy whose weakness plainly threatens all Americans’ well-being.

 

The immigration realists’ success has shaped the national political landscape for so long that it is all too easy to take for granted. It shouldn’t be. Nor should the powerful interests they have frustrated be overlooked. Save for desperate gambits like Obama’s new deportation policy end-run, the realists have not only blocked the Open Borders agenda for years. They have prevailed over an even stronger coalition than that faced by the trade realists.

 

Both groups of economic realists have been battling Big Business, Big Agriculture, Wall Street, and the mainstream media. But the immigration policy critics are also opposed by a union movement that stands with the trade realists, and by the leadership of the Democratic party. It’s true that immigration realism is now endorsed — to varying degrees — by most Republican party kingpins. But this development is fairly recent. Previously, these Big Business-friendly politicians — including, of course, former President George W. Bush and 2008 Republican presidential nominee Sen. John McCain of Arizona — were active Open Borders advocates.[26]

 

Summary of the Meltdown and Great Recession

 

To conclude, the causes underlying the great mortgage crisis and recession can be summarized as follows. First of all the American economy was increasingly hollowed out as a result of these factors: the cult of diversity and affirmative action arising from the ideology of the 60s generation; mass low wage and low skilled chain immigration resulting from legislation beginning in the 1960s; the free trade and globalization imperatives of the last few decades. These were accompanied by an explosion of financial innovation due to massive debt, globalization and subprime mortgage securitization. This was aggravated by Wall Street greed, ineffective regulators and a housing bubble due to easy money. Affirmative action and immigration impelled subprime mortgages while the Wall Street machine’s financial innovation made them possible. The mortgage meltdown was the inevitable result. The subsequent recession was made more intractable due to the hollowed out economy and the ineffectiveness of economic stimulus owing to leakages as a result of both the trade deficit and immigrant remittances.



[1] Michael Cutler, “Immigration — The Modern Day ‘Gold Rush’”, Social Contract Journal, Spring 2012 , p. 43.
[2] Ibid
[3] Sean Trende, “The Case of the Missing White Voters”, November 8, 2012, http://www.realclearpolitics.com/articles/2012/11/08/the_case_of_the_missing_white_voters_116106-2.html
[4] Alan Tonelson, “Immigration Realists Need to Focus on Trade Policy”, Social Contract Journal, Summer 2012, p.10.
[5] Ian Fletcher, “The Case against Free Trade”, Social Contract Journal, Summer 2012, p.5.
[6] Ibid
[7] John Fonte, “Dogmatic Libertarians Over the edge” May 9, 2002, http://old.nationalreview.com/comment/comment-fonte050902.asp
[8] Robert Rector, “Look to Milton: Open borders and the welfare state”, June 20, 2007, http://www.nationalreview.com/articles/221330/look-milton/robert-rector
[9] Jason Riley, “Let Them In” Wall Street Journal, May 16, 2008.
[10] Mac Johnson, A Nation of Widgets: The Wall Street Journal and Open Borders, December 12, 2005, http://www.humanevents.com/2005/12/12/a-nation-of-widgets-the-wall-street-journal-and-open-borders/
[11] See his critique of those economists who pushed for a much too rapid transition to free markets in chapter 5, “Who Lost Russia” in Joseph Stiglitz, Globalization and its Discontents, New York, Norton, 2002.
[12] Stiglitz, Freefall, p. 9.
[13] Ibid, p. 177.
[14] Ibid, p. 181.
[15] Ibid, pp. 103-104.
[16] Ibid, p. 165.
[17] Ibid, p. 280.
[18] Ibid, pp. 174-179.
[19] Ibid, p. 170.
[20] Ibid, pp. 192-194.
[21] Ibid, pp. 196-97.
[22] Ingrid Carlqvist, “Toto, I Have A Feeling We’re Not In Sweden Anymore”, Gates of Vienna, July 15, 2012.
[23] Stiglitz, p. 222.
[24] Ibid, p. 221.
[25] Ibid, pp. 60-63.
[26] Tonelson, “Immigration Realists Need to Focus on Trade Policy”,  p.7.